Abstract
We obtain explicit representations of locally risk-minimizing strategies for call and put options in Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard models, which are Ornstein–Uhlenbeck-type stochastic volatility models. Using Malliavin calculus for Lévy processes, Arai and Suzuki (Int. J. Financ. Eng. 2:1550015, 2015) obtained a formula for locally risk-minimizing strategies for Lévy markets under many additional conditions. Supposing mild conditions, we make sure that the Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard models satisfy all the conditions imposed in (Arai and Suzuki in Int. J. Financ. Eng. 2:1550015, 2015). Among others, we investigate the Malliavin differentiability of the density of the minimal martingale measure. Moreover, we introduce some numerical experiments for locally risk-minimizing strategies.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Arai, T.: Local risk-minimization for Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard models with volatility risk premium. Adv. Math. Econ. 20, 3–22 (2016)
Arai, T., Imai, Y., Suzuki, R.: Numerical analysis on local risk-minimization for exponential Lévy models. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Finance 19, 1650008 (2016)
Arai, T., Suzuki, R.: Local risk minimization for Lévy markets. Int. J. Financ. Eng. 2, 1550015 (2015)
Barndorff-Nielsen, O.E., Shephard, N.: Modelling by Lévy processes for financial econometrics. In: Barndorff-Nielsen, O.E., et al. (eds.) Lévy Processes—Theory and Applications, pp. 283–318. Birkhäuser, Basel (2001)
Barndorff-Nielsen, O.E., Shephard, N.: Non-Gaussian Ornstein–Uhlenbeck based models and some of their uses in financial econometrics. J. R. Stat. Soc., Ser. B, Stat. Methodol. 63, 167–241 (2001)
Benth, F.E., Detering, N.: Pricing and hedging Asian-style options in energy. Finance Stoch. 19, 849–889 (2015)
Carr, P., Madan, D.: Option valuation using the fast Fourier transform. J. Comput. Finance 2, 61–73 (1999)
Cont, R., Tankov, P.: Financial Modelling with Jump Processes. Chapman & Hall/CRC Press, London/Boca Raton (2004)
Cont, R., Tankov, P., Voltchkova, E.: Hedging with options in models with jumps. In: Benth, F., et al. (eds.) Stochastic Analysis and Applications. The Abel Symposium 2005, pp. 197–217. Springer, Berlin (2007)
Delong, Ł., Imkeller, P.: On Malliavin’s differentiability of BSDEs with time delayed generators driven by Brownian motions and Poisson random measures. Stoch. Process. Appl. 120, 1748–1775 (2010)
Di Nunno, G., Øksendal, B., Proske, F.: Malliavin Calculus for Lévy Processes with Applications to Finance. Springer, Berlin (2009)
Ishikawa, Y.: Stochastic Calculus of Variations for Jump Processes. de Gruyter, Berlin (2013)
Kallsen, J., Pauwels, A.: Variance-optimal hedging in general affine stochastic volatility models. Adv. Appl. Probab. 42, 83–105 (2010)
Kallsen, J., Vierthauer, R.: Quadratic hedging in affine stochastic volatility models. Rev. Deriv. Res. 12, 3–27 (2009)
Nicolato, E., Venardos, E.: Option pricing in stochastic volatility models of the Ornstein–Uhlenbeck type. Math. Finance 13, 445–466 (2003)
Protter, P.: Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin (2004)
Schoutens, W.: Lévy Processes in Finance: Pricing Financial Derivatives. Wiley, Hoboken (2003)
Schweizer, M.: A guided tour through quadratic hedging approaches. In: Jouini, E., et al. (eds.) Option Pricing, Interest Rates and Risk Management. Handbooks in Mathematical Finance, pp. 538–574. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2001)
Schweizer, M.: Local risk-minimization for multidimensional assets and payment streams. Banach Cent. Publ. 83, 213–229 (2008)
Situ, R.: Theory of Stochastic Differential Equations with Jumps and Applications. Mathematical and Analytical Techniques with Applications to Engineering. Springer, Berlin (2005)
Solé, J.L., Utzet, F., Vives, J.: Canonical Lévy process and Malliavin calculus. Stoch. Process. Appl. 117, 165–187 (2007)
Suzuki, R.: A Clark–Ocone type formula under change of measure for Lévy processes with \(L^{2}\)-Lévy measure. Commun. Stoch. Anal. 7, 383–407 (2013)
Acknowledgements
Takuji Arai gratefully acknowledges the financial support of Ishii Memorial Securities Research Promotion Foundation and Scientific Research (C) No. 15K04936 from the Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology of Japan.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
1.1 A.1 Theorem 3.7 of [3]
Theorem 3.7 of [3], which provides an explicit representation formula for LRM strategies in Lévy markets, is frequently referred to in this paper. Therefore, we give its statement for BNS models under Assumption 2.2. Note that although Assumption 2.1 of [3] is imposed in Theorem 3.7 of [3], it is satisfied under Assumption 2.2. For more details, see Remark 2.3.
Theorem A.1
(Theorem 3.7 of [3])
Let \(F\) be an \(L^{2}({\mathbb {P}})\) random variable satisfying the following three conditions:
AS1: (Assumption 2.6 in [3]) \(Z_{T}F\) is in \(L^{2}({\mathbb {P}})\).
AS2: (Assumption 3.4 in [3]) Conditions (C1)–(C6) for \(F\) are satisfied.
AS3: ((3.1) in [3]) We have
where \(h_{t,z}^{1}={\mathbb {E}}_{{\mathbb {P}}^{*}}[F(H^{*}_{t,z}-1)+zH^{*}_{t,z}D_{t,z}F|{\mathcal {F}} _{t-}]\) and
Then the LRM strategy \(\xi^{F}\) for the claim \(F\) is given by
1.2 A.2 Properties of \(\sigma_{t}\) and related Malliavin derivatives
The squared volatility process \((\sigma_{t}^{2})\), given as a solution to the SDE (1.2), is represented as
Remark that we have
and
Next, we calculate some related Malliavin derivatives.
Lemma A.2
For any \(s\in[0,T]\), we have \(\sigma_{s}^{2}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\).
Proof
We can rewrite (A.1) as
Moreover, we have \(\int_{[0,T]\times[0,\infty)}e^{-2\lambda(s-u)}{\mathbf{1}}_{[0,s]\times(0,\infty)}(u,x)q(du,dx)<\infty\). The lemma follows by Definition 2.8. □
Lemma A.3
For any \(s\in[0,T]\), we have \(\sigma_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\). Furthermore, we have \(0\leq D_{t,z}\sigma_{s}\leq\frac{1}{\sqrt{z}}{\mathbf{1}}_{[0,s]}(t)\) for \(z>0\).
Proof
Taking a \(C^{1}\)-function \(f\) such that \(f^{\prime}\) is bounded and \(f(r) = \sqrt{r}\) for \(r\geq e^{-\lambda T}\sigma_{0}^{2}\), we have \(\sigma_{s}=f(\sigma_{s}^{2})\) by (A.2). Proposition 2.6 in [22] implies that we have \(\sigma_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}} ^{1,2}\), \(D_{t,0}\sigma_{s}=f^{\prime}(\sigma_{s}^{2})D_{t,0}\sigma_{s}^{2}=0\), and
for \(z>0\) since \(D_{t,z}\sigma_{s}^{2}\) is nonnegative by (A.4). In addition, we have
for \(z>0\). □
Lemma A.4
We have \(\int_{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}^{2}ds\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\), where the function ℬ is defined just before Assumption 2.2.
Proof
First, we have
From Definition 2.8 we obtain \(\int_{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}^{2}ds\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times(0,\infty)\). □
Lemma A.5
We have \(\int_{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}dW_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\).
Proof
To begin, we show that \(\sigma\in{\mathbb {L}}_{0}^{1,2}\). Lemma A.3 implies that \(\sigma_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) for any \(s\in[0,T]\). We have \({\mathbb {E}}[\int_{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}^{2}ds]<\infty\) by (A.3) and the integrability of \(J_{T}\). Since \(|D_{t,z}\sigma_{s}|^{2}\le\frac{1}{z}\) by Lemma A.3, item (c) of the definition of \({\mathbb {L}}_{0}^{1,2}\) is satisfied. Hence, Lemma 3.3 in [10] provides \(\int_{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}dW_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}} ^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\) by Lemma A.3. □
Finally, we calculate \(D_{t,z}L_{T}\) as follows.
Proposition A.6
\(L_{T}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\), and for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\), we have
Proof
By (2.1) we have \(L_{T}=\mu T-\frac{1}{2}\int_{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}^{2}ds+\int _{0}^{T}\sigma_{s}dW_{s}+\rho J_{T}\). Since \(J_{T}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and \(D_{t,z}J_{T}={\mathbf{1}}_{(0,\infty)}(z)\), we obtain the result by Lemmas A.4 and A.5. □
1.3 A.3 Properties of \(u_{s}\) and \(\theta_{s,x}\) and related Malliavin derivatives
We begin with recalling the two constants defined in (2.2):
The next lemma is cited often throughout the paper.
Lemma A.7
For any \(s\in[0,T]\) and any \(x\in(0,\infty)\), the following hold:
1. \(|u_{s}|\leq C_{u}\).
2. \(|\theta_{s,x}|\leq C_{\theta}\) and \(|\theta_{s,x}|\leq C_{\theta}(1-e^{\rho x})\leq C_{\theta}|\rho|x\).
3. \(\theta_{s,x}<1-e^{\rho x}\).
4. \(|\log(1-\theta_{s,x})|\leq C_{\theta}|\rho|x\).
5. \(\frac{1}{1-\theta_{s,x}}<\hat{C}_{\theta}\) for some \(\hat{C}_{\theta}>0\).
Proof
1. We have \(|u_{s}|\leq\frac{|\alpha|}{\sigma_{s}}\leq\frac{|\alpha|e^{\frac {\lambda T}{2}}}{\sigma_{0}}\) for any \(s\in[0,T]\) by (A.2).
2. \(|\theta_{s,x}|\leq\frac{|\alpha|}{C_{\rho}}(1-e^{\rho x})\leq C_{\theta}\) and \(1-e^{\rho x}\leq|\rho|x\) for any \(x>0\).
3. As seen in Remark 2.3, \(\frac{\alpha}{\sigma^{2}_{s}+C_{\rho}}>-1\) for any \(s\in[0,T]\). We have then \(\theta_{s,x}<1-e^{\rho x}\).
4. When \(\theta_{s,x}\geq0\), we have
On the other hand, if \(\theta_{s,x}< 0\), then \(0<\log(1-\theta _{s,x})\leq-\theta_{s,x}\leq C_{\theta}|\rho|x\).
5. If \(\theta_{s,x}\leq0\), then \(\frac{1}{1-\theta_{s,x}}\leq1\); otherwise, if \(\theta_{s,x}>0\), equivalently \(\alpha<0\), then
by Assumption 2.2. This completes the proof. □
Next, we calculate some Malliavin derivatives related to \(u_{s}\) and \(\theta_{s,x}\).
Lemma A.8
For any \(s\in[0,T]\), we have \(u_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\), where \(f_{u}(r) := \frac{\alpha r}{r^{2}+C_{\rho}}\) for \(r\in{\mathbb {R}}\). Moreover, we have
for some \(C_{u}^{\prime}>0\).
Proof
Note that \(f^{\prime}_{u}(r)=\alpha\frac{C_{\rho}-r^{2}}{(r^{2}+C_{\rho})^{2}}\) and \(|f^{\prime}_{u}(r)|\leq\frac{|\alpha|}{C_{\rho}}\leq C_{u}\). Since \(u_{s}=f_{u}(\sigma_{s})\) and \(\sigma_{s}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\), Proposition 2.6 in [22], together with Lemma A.3, implies \(u_{s}\in {\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and (A.5). In particular, we have \(D_{t,0}u_{s} = f^{\prime}_{u}(\sigma_{s})D_{t,0}\sigma _{s} = 0\). Further, Lemma A.3 again yields \(|D_{t,z}u_{s}|\leq\frac {1}{z}|zD_{t,z}\sigma_{s}|C_{u}\leq\frac{1}{\sqrt{z}}{\mathbf{1}}_{[0,s]}(t)C_{u}\). Moreover, since \(f_{u}(r)\) is bounded, we can find a \(C_{u}^{\prime}>0\) such that \(|D_{t,z}u_{s}|\leq\frac{C_{u}^{\prime}}{z}\). □
Lemma A.9
For any \((s,x)\in[0,T]\times(0,\infty)\), we have \(\theta_{s,x}\in{\mathbb {D}} ^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\), where \(f_{\theta}(r) := \frac{\alpha }{r^{2}+C_{\rho}}\) for \(r\in{\mathbb {R}}\). Moreover, we have
for some \(C_{\theta}^{\prime}>0\).
Proof
Note that \(\theta_{s,x}=f_{\theta}(\sigma_{s})(e^{\rho x}-1)\) and \(f^{\prime}_{\theta}(r)=-\frac{2\alpha r}{(r^{2}+C_{\rho})^{2}}\). Hence, \(|f^{\prime}_{\theta}(r)|\) is bounded. Therefore, the same argument as for Lemma A.8 implies (A.6). In addition, (A.7) is given by the boundedness of \(f_{\theta}\) and \(f_{\theta}^{\prime}\). □
Lemma A.10
For any \((s,x)\in[0,T]\times(0,\infty)\), we have \(\log(1-\theta _{s,x})\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and
for \((t,z)\in[0,T]\times[0,\infty)\). Moreover, we have
Proof
For \(x>0\), we denote
Note that \(g_{x}\) is a \(C^{1}\)-function satisfying \(|g^{\prime}_{x}(r)|\leq e^{-\rho x}\) for all \(r\in{\mathbb {R}}\). Because \(\theta_{s,x}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and \(\log(1-\theta_{s,x})=g_{x}(\theta _{s,x})\) by item 3 of Lemma A.7, we have
Lemma A.9 implies, for \(t\in[0,s]\) and \(z\in(0,\infty)\),
We have then \(g_{x}(\theta_{s,x}+zD_{t,z}\theta_{s,x})=\log(1-\theta _{s,x}-zD_{t,z}\theta_{s,x})\). □
1.4 A.4 On \(D_{t,z}\log Z_{T}\)
We show that \(\log Z_{T}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\) and calculate \(D_{t,z}\log Z_{T}\). Equality (2.5) implies that
We discuss each term of (A.9) separately. As seen in Sect. 4, we have \(u\in{\mathbb {L}}_{0}^{1,2}\). Therefore, Lemma 3.3 of [10] implies that
and \(D_{t,z}\int_{0}^{T}u_{s}dW_{s}=\int_{0}^{T}D_{t,z}u_{s}dW_{s}\) for \(z>0\). Similarly, we have
and
for \(z>0\). As for \(D_{t,z}\int_{0}^{T}u_{s}^{2}ds\), because \(u^{2}\in{\mathbb {L}}_{0}^{1,2}\) by Sect. 4, Lemma 3.2 of [10] yields
for \(z\geq0\). In particular, \(D_{t,0}\int_{0}^{T}u_{s}^{2}ds=0\). For the fourth term of (A.9), because \(\log(1-\theta)+\theta\in\widetilde{{\mathbb {L}} }_{1}^{1,2}\), Proposition 3.5 of [22] implies
for \(z\geq0\). Collectively, we conclude the following:
Proposition A.11
We have \(\log Z_{T}\in{\mathbb {D}}^{1,2}\), \(D_{t,0}\log Z_{T}=u_{t}\), and
for \(z>0\).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Arai, T., Imai, Y. & Suzuki, R. Local risk-minimization for Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard models. Finance Stoch 21, 551–592 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-017-0324-8
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-017-0324-8
Keywords
- Local risk-minimization
- Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard models
- Stochastic volatility models
- Malliavin calculus
- Lévy processes