[go: up one dir, main page]
More Web Proxy on the site http://driver.im/ Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Endogenizing the sticks and carrots: modeling possible perverse effects of counterterrorism measures

  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We present a novel model capable of distinguishing between the effects of negative incentives (“sticks”) and positive incentives (“carrots”) for influencing the behavior of intelligent and adaptable adversaries. Utilities are developed for the defender and the terrorist. The defender is assumed to have a unit cost of defense, and unit costs of providing negative and positive incentives. The terrorist likewise has a unit cost of attack, which may either increase or decrease if the defender provides negative incentives, and enjoys a unit benefit of positive incentives. We show that the potential for perverse effects of counterterrorism (e.g., the emergence of hatred) can cause defenders to rely on positive incentives and decrease their reliance on negative incentives at equilibrium, with use of negative incentives completely eliminated in situations where these would be moderately effective when applied. With low potential for perverse effects of counterterrorism, the defender should rely on effective negative incentives.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
£29.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (United Kingdom)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aumann, R., & Maschler, M. (1995). Repeated games with incomplete information. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandyopadhyay, S., & Sandler, T. (2011). The interplay between preemptive and defensive counterterrorism measures: A two-stage game. Economica. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.2009.00823.x.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bier, V. M., Oliveros, S., & Samuelson, L. (2007). Choosing what to protect: strategic defensive allocation against an unknown attacker. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 9, 563–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, P. (1999). Varieties of pacifism: A survey from antiquity to the outset of the twentieth century. New York: Syracuse University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burton, F. (2008). Ghost: confessions of a counterterrorism agent. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dalvi, N., Domingos, P., Mausam, M., Sanghai, S., & Verma, D. (2004). Adversarial classification. In Proceedings of the 2004 ACM SIGKDD international conference on knowledge discovery and data mining, Seattle, WA (pp. 99–108).

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dirks, T. (1969), Review of “Butch Cassidy and the Sundance Kid (1969)”, http://www.filmsite.org/butc3.html.

  • Enders, W., & Sandler, T. (2004). What do we know about the substitution effect in transnational terrorism. In A. Silke & G. Ilardi (Eds.), Research on terrorism: trends, achievements and failures. London: Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (2004). Dealing with terrorism: stick or carrot. Northampton: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Luechinger, S. (2003). How to fight terrorism: alternatives to deterrence. Defense and Peace Economics, 14, 237–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganor, B. (2005). The counter-terrorism puzzle: a guide for decision makers. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L. (2005). The political economy of hatred. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 45–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausken, K. (2006). Income, interdependence, and substitution effects affecting incentives for security investment. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 25, 629–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobbes, T. (1651). Leviathan. London: Dent.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, B. (1998). Inside terrorism. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, B. (2001), All you need is love, The Atlantic, http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/200112/hoffman.

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1995). Anarchy and its breakdown. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 26–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, N., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (2003). The ecology of terror defense. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 26, 201–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lakdawalla, D., & Zanjani, G. (2005). Insurance, self-protection, and the economics of terrorism. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 1891–1905.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lutfi, A. (2001). Blowback: China and the Afghan Arabs. Issues and Studies, 37(1), 160–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obama, B. H. 2009. The Nobel peace prize lecture, Oslo, December 10, 2009, http://nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/peace/laureates/2009/obama-lecture_en.html.

  • Machiavelli, N. (1492). The prince. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pruitt, D. G. (2006). Negotiation with terrorists. International Negotiation, 11(2), 371–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salop, S. C., & Scheffman, D. T. (1983). Raising rivals’ costs. American Economic Review, 73, 267–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T., Arce, D. G., & Enders, W. (2008). Copenhagen consensus 2008 challenge paper: terrorism.

  • Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S. (1996). Contest success functions. Economic Theory, 7, 283–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spector, B. I. (1998). Deciding to negotiate with villains. Negotiation Journal, 14(1), 43–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spector, B. I. (2003). Negotiating with villains revisited: research note. International Negotiation, 8(3), 616–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tzu, S. (320 Before Christ). The art of war. Translated by Griffith, S.B. (1963). London: Oxford University Press.

  • Tirole, J. (1989). The theory of industrial organization. New York: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5, 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kjell Hausken.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bier, V.M., Hausken, K. Endogenizing the sticks and carrots: modeling possible perverse effects of counterterrorism measures. Ann Oper Res 186, 39–59 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-010-0833-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-010-0833-8

Keywords

Navigation