Abstract
We study continuous-time optimal consumption and investment with Epstein–Zin recursive preferences in incomplete markets. We develop a novel approach that rigorously constructs the solution of the associated Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation by a fixed point argument and makes it possible to compute both the indirect utility and, more importantly, optimal strategies. Based on these results, we also establish a fast and accurate method for numerical computations. Our setting is not restricted to affine asset price dynamics; we only require boundedness of the underlying model coefficients.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Machine: Intel® Core™ i3-540 Processor (4M Cache, 3.06 GHz), 4 GB RAM.
Here we slightly abuse notation since \(\langle u\rangle^{q}_{x}\) has only been defined for functions on \([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d}\). Of course, for \(u:\ \mathbb{R}^{d}\to \mathbb{R}\) and \(q\in(0,1)\), we understand that \(\langle u\rangle^{q}_{x} :=\sup_{x,x' \in \mathbb{R}^{d},\ |x-x'| \leq 1} \frac {|u(x) - u(x')|}{|x-x'|^{q}}\).
References
Antonelli, F.: Stability of backward stochastic differential equations. Stoch. Process. Appl. 62, 103–114 (1996)
Barberis, N.C.: Investing for the long run when returns are predictable. J. Finance 55, 225–264 (2000)
Berdjane, B., Pergamenshchikov, S.: Optimal consumption and investment for markets with random coefficients. Finance Stoch. 17, 419–446 (2013)
Bertoldi, M., Lorenzi, L.: Estimates of the derivatives for parabolic operators with unbounded coefficients. Trans. Am. Math. Soc. 357, 2627–2664 (2005)
Briand, P., Carmona, R.: BSDEs with polynomial growth generators. J. Appl. Math. Stoch. Anal. 13, 207–238 (2000)
Briand, P., Hu, Y.: Quadratic BSDEs with convex generators and unbounded terminal conditions. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 141, 543–567 (2008)
Campbell, J.Y., Chacko, G., Rodriguez, J., Viceira, L.M.: Strategic asset allocation in a continuous-time VAR model. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 128, 2195–2214 (2004)
Campbell, J.Y., Viceira, L.M.: Consumption and portfolio decisions when expected returns are time varying. Q. J. Econ. 114, 433–495 (1999)
Campbell, J.Y., Viceira, L.M.: Strategic Asset Allocation. Oxford University Press, London (2002)
Cerrai, S.: Elliptic and parabolic equations in \(\mathbb{R}^{n}\) with coefficients having polynomial growth. Commun. Partial Differ. Equ. 21, 281–317 (1996)
Cerrai, S.: Second order PDEs. In: Finite and Infinite Dimension. Springer, Berlin (2001)
Chacko, G., Viceira, L.M.: Dynamic consumption and portfolio choice with stochastic volatility in incomplete markets. Rev. Financ. Stud. 18, 1369–1402 (2005)
Christoffersen, P., Jacobs, K., Mimouni, K.: Volatility dynamics for the S&P500: evidence from realized volatility, daily returns, and option prices. Rev. Financ. Stud. 23, 3141–3189 (2010)
Cochrane, J.Y.: A mean-variance benchmark for intertemporal portfolio theory. J. Finance 69, 1–49 (2014)
Delarue, F.: On the existence and uniqueness of solutions to FBSDEs in a non-degenerate case. Stoch. Process. Appl. 99, 209–286 (2002)
Delbaen, F., Hu, Y., Richou, A.: On the uniqueness of solutions to quadratic BSDEs with convex generators and unbounded terminal conditions. Ann. Inst. Henri Poincaré B, Probab. Stat. 47, 559–574 (2011)
Duffie, D., Epstein, L.G.: Stochastic differential utility. Econometrica 60, 353–394 (1992)
Duffie, D., Lions, P.L.: PDE solutions of stochastic differential utility. J. Math. Econ. 21, 577–606 (1992)
Duffie, D., Skiadas, C.: Continuous-time security pricing. J. Math. Econ. 23, 107–131 (1994)
El Karoui, N., Peng, S., Quenez, M.C.: Backward stochastic differential equations in finance. Math. Finance 7, 1–71 (1997)
Elworthy, K., Li, X.M.: Formulae for the derivatives of heat semigroups. J. Funct. Anal. 125, 252–286 (1994)
Epstein, L.G., Zin, S.E.: Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica 57, 937–969 (1989)
Heston, S.L.: A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to bond and currency options. Rev. Financ. Stud. 6, 327–343 (1993)
Kim, T.S., Omberg, E.: Dynamic nonmyopic portfolio behavior. Rev. Financ. Stud. 9, 141–161 (1996)
Kobylanski, M.: Backward stochastic differential equations and partial differential equations with quadratic growth. Ann. Appl. Probab. 28, 558–602 (2000)
Kraft, H., Seifried, F.T., Steffensen, M.: Consumption-portfolio optimization with recursive utility in incomplete markets. Finance Stoch. 17, 161–196 (2013)
Kreps, D.M., Porteus, E.L.: Temporal resolution of uncertainty and dynamic choice theory. Econometrica 46, 185–200 (1978)
Kreps, D.M., Porteus, E.L.: Temporal von Neumann–Morgenstern and induced preferences. J. Econ. Theory 20, 81–109 (1979)
Ladyzenskaja, O.A., Solonnikov, V., Ural’ceva, N.: Linear and Quasi-Linear Equations of Parabolic Type. Am. Math. Soc., Providence (1968)
Liu, J.: Portfolio selection in stochastic environments. Rev. Financ. Stud. 20, 1–39 (2007)
Liu, J., Pan, J.: Dynamic derivative strategies. J. Financ. Econ. 69, 401–430 (2003)
Ma, J., Protter, P., Yong, J.: Solving forward-backward stochastic differential equations explicitly—a four step scheme. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 98, 339–359 (1994)
Ma, J., Yin, H., Zhang, J.: On non-Markovian forward-backward SDEs and backward stochastic PDEs. Stoch. Process. Appl. 122, 3980–4004 (2012)
Marinacci, M., Montrucchio, L.: Unique solutions for stochastic recursive utilities. J. Econ. Theory 145, 1776–1804 (2010)
Pardoux, E., Peng, S.: Backward stochastic differential equations and quasilinear parabolic differential equations. In: Rozovskii, B.L., Sowers, R.B. (eds.) Stochastic Partial Differential Equations and Their Applications. Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences, vol. 176, pp. 200–217 (1992)
Schroder, M., Skiadas, C.: Optimal consumption and portfolio selection with stochastic differential utility. J. Econ. Theory 89, 68–126 (1999)
Schroder, M., Skiadas, C.: Optimal lifetime consumption-portfolio strategies under trading constraints and generalized recursive preferences. Stoch. Process. Appl. 108, 155–202 (2003)
Schroder, M., Skiadas, C.: Lifetime consumption-portfolio choice under trading constraints, recursive preferences, and nontradeable income. Stoch. Process. Appl. 115, 1–30 (2005)
Schroder, M., Skiadas, C.: Optimality and state pricing in constrained financial markets with recursive utility under continuous and discontinuous information. Math. Finance 2, 199–238 (2008)
Seiferling, T., Seifried, F.T.: Epstein–Zin stochastic differential utility: Existence, uniqueness, concavity, and utility gradients. Working paper (2016). Available online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2625800
Wachter, J.A.: Portfolio and consumption decisions under mean-reverting returns: an exact solution for complete markets. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 37, 63–91 (2002)
Xing, H.: Consumption–investment optimization with Epstein–Zin utility in incomplete markets. Finance Stoch. 21 (this issue, 2017). doi:10.1007/s00780-016-0297-z
Zariphopoulou, T.: A solution approach to valuation with unhedgeable risks. Finance Stoch. 5, 61–82 (2001)
Acknowledgements
All authors wish to thank Jakša Cvitanić (editor), the Associate Editor and two referees (anonymous) for very helpful comments. We thank Darrell Duffie, Bernard Dumas, Francis Longstaff, Claus Munk, Lukas Schmid, and Carsten Sørensen for very helpful discussions, comments and suggestions. We also thank the participants of the Bachelier Finance Society 8th World Congress, the 11th German Probability and Stochastics Days, the 9th Bachelier Colloquium and seminar participants at ETH Zürich, Copenhagen Business School, the University of Copenhagen, and the University of Southern Denmark for many helpful comments and suggestions. Holger Kraft gratefully acknowledges financial support from Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG) and the Center of Excellence SAFE, funded by the State of Hessen initiative for research LOEWE. Thomas Seiferling gratefully acknowledges financial support from Studienstiftung des Deutschen Volkes.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix A: Proofs omitted from the main text
Proof of Lemma 4.6
Since \(h\) solves the reduced HJB equation (4.7), we have
where \(z:=(t,x,y, w_{x}, w_{y}, w_{x_{y}} w_{xx}, w_{yy})\). Separating the terms in the function \(H\) as \(H(z, \pi ,c) :=u(z, \pi) + s(z, c) + q(z) \), it is easy to see that the candidate solutions \(\hat{\pi}\) and \(\hat{c}\) defined in (4.6) are the unique solutions of the associated first-order conditions
Concavity of \(u\) and \(s\) implies that \(H(z, \hat{\pi}, \hat{c}) = { \sup_{\pi\in \mathbb{R},\, c\in(0,\infty)}} H(z, \pi ,c)\). □
Proof of Lemma 4.7
By (A1) and (A2), \(\tilde{\alpha}\) and \(\tilde{r}\) are bounded. Moreover,
so that \(\tilde{\alpha}\) is Lipschitz-continuous. Finally,
□
Proof of Lemma 5.3
The candidate optimal wealth process \(\hat{X}\) has dynamics
Put \(a_{t}:=r_{t} + \frac{1}{\gamma}\frac{\lambda_{t}^{2}}{\sigma_{t}^{2}}+ \frac{k}{\gamma}\frac{\lambda_{t}\beta_{t} \rho}{\sigma_{t}} \frac{h_{y}}{h} - \delta^{\psi}h^{q-1}\) and \(b_{t}:=\frac{1}{\gamma}\frac{\lambda_{t}}{\sigma_{t}} + \frac{k}{\gamma}\beta_{t} \rho \frac {h_{y}}{h}\). Our assumptions on the coefficients and on \(h_{y}\) and \(h\) imply that both \(a\) and \(b\) are bounded. By Itô’s formula,
where \(\mathcal {E}_{t}({\,\cdot \,})\) denotes the stochastic exponential. Choose the constant \(M>0\) such that \(|p a_{t}| + |p(p-1) b_{t}^{2}|, |p b_{t}| < M\) for all \(t\in[0,T]\). By Novikov’s condition, \({\mathcal {E}}_{t} (p\int_{0}^{{\,\cdot \,}}b_{s} \,\mathrm{d} W_{s} )\) is then an \(L^{2}\)-martingale; so using Doob’s \(L^{2}\)-inequality, we get
□
Proof of Lemma 5.4
Lemma 5.3 and the boundedness of \(\delta^{\psi}h(t,Y_{t})^{q-1}\) imply that \(\operatorname{E}[ {\sup_{t\in[0,T]}} |\hat{c}_{t}|^{p} ] < \infty\) for all \(p \in \mathbb{R}\). In particular, \(\hat{c} \) is in \(\mathcal{C}\). By Itô’s formula,
where \(M\) is a local martingale. Hence \(\mathrm{d} V_{t} = - f(\hat{c}_{t}, V_{t}) \,\mathrm{d} t + \,\mathrm{d} M_{t}\) by Lemma 4.6. Moreover, exploiting the special form of \(w\), we get
Here \(V_{t}\) can be rewritten as \(V_{t} = w(t, \hat{X}_{t}, Y_{t}) = \frac{1}{1-\gamma} \hat{X}_{t}^{1-\gamma} h(t,Y_{t})^{k}\). By (4.8), the function \(h\) is bounded and bounded away from zero. Thus we have for all \(p \in \mathbb{R}\) by Lemma 5.3 that \(\operatorname{E}[{\sup_{t\in[0,T]}} |V_{t}|^{p} ] <\infty\). Hence \(V\) is a utility process associated with \(\hat{c}\); by (E1), it follows that \(V=V^{\hat{c}}\). Finally, the first-order condition (A.1) for the optimal consumption implies that \(w_{x}(t, \hat{X}_{t}, Y_{t}) = f_{c}(t, w(t, \hat{X}_{t}, Y_{t})) = f_{c}(\hat{c}_{t}, \hat{V}_{t})\). □
Proof of Lemma 5.5
For simplicity of notation, we set \(r_{t}:=r(Y_{t})\), \(\lambda_{t}:=\lambda(Y_{t})\) and \(\sigma_{t}:=\sigma(Y_{t})\). We have \(\mathrm{d} Z^{\pi, c}_{t} = \hat{m}_{t} c_{t} \,\mathrm{d} t + \hat{m}_{t} \,\mathrm{d} X_{t}^{\pi,c} + X_{t}^{\pi ,c} \,\mathrm{d} \hat{m}_{t} + \,\mathrm{d} [\hat{m},X^{\pi,c}]_{t}\) by the product rule. Inserting the dynamics of \(X^{\pi ,c}\) from (4.1), we get
By Lemma 5.4, \(\hat{V}_{t}=w(t,\hat{X}_{t},Y_{t})\) and \(\hat{m}_{t} = e^{\int_{0}^{t} f_{v}(\hat{c}_{s}, \hat{V}_{s}) \,\mathrm{d} s} w_{x}(t,\hat{X}_{t},Y_{t})\). From here on, we abbreviate \(f_{v} = f_{v}(\hat{c}_{t}, \hat{V}_{t})\), \(w_{x} = w_{x}(t, \hat{X}_{t}, Y_{t})\) etc. Clearly, we have \(\mathrm{d} \hat{m}_{t} = \hat{m}_{t} ( f_{v} \,\mathrm{d} t + \frac{\mathrm{d} w_{x}}{w_{x}} )\).
From the explicit expression \(f_{v}(c, v) = \delta \frac {\phi -\gamma}{1-\phi} c^{1 -\phi} ((1-\gamma)v)^{\frac{\phi-1}{1-\gamma}} - \delta \theta\), we obtain \(f_{v}(\hat{c}_{t}, w(t, \hat{X}_{t}, Y_{t}))= \frac{\phi-\gamma}{1-\phi} \delta^{\psi} h^{q -1} - \delta\theta\). By Itô’s formula,
Substituting for \(w\), we find
Plugging in the candidate \(\hat{\pi}\) from (5.1) and the dynamics of \(\hat{X}\) and \(Y\) yields
where
For the sum of the \(\frac {h_{y}^{2}}{h^{2}}\)-terms, we have
by our choice of \(k\). Combining the above, we obtain
and it follows that \(\mathrm{d} [\hat{m}, X^{\pi , c}]_{t} = - \lambda_{t} \pi_{t} \hat{m}_{t} X_{t}^{\pi,c} \,\mathrm{d} t\). Since \(h\) solves (4.7), we get
where \(\mathrm{d} M_{t}:=\hat{m}_{t} X_{t}^{\pi,c} ((\pi_{t} \sigma_{t} - \frac {\lambda_{t}}{\sigma _{t}} ) \,\mathrm{d} W_{t} + k\sqrt{1- \rho^{2}}\beta_{t} \frac {h_{y}}{h} \,\mathrm{d} \bar{W}_{t} )\) defines a local martingale \(M\). A direct calculation using the definition of \(\hat{\pi}\) yields the statement for \(Z^{\hat{\pi}, \hat{c}}\). □
Proof of Lemma 5.6
Recall that \(\underline{h}\leq h\leq \overline{h}\) so that
and we get \(0 \leq \exp(p{\int_{0}^{T}} f_{v}(\hat{c}_{s}, \hat{V}_{s}) \,\mathrm{d} s ) \leq e^{Tp m_{1}}\). On the other hand, Lemma 5.4 implies that \(\operatorname{E}[{\sup_{t \in [0,T]}} f_{c}(\hat{c}_{t}, \hat{V}_{t})^{p}] < \infty\) for all \(p \in \mathbb{R}\). It follows that
To show that \(Z^{\hat{\pi}, \hat{c}}\) is a martingale, note that \(\frac {1- \gamma}{\gamma}\frac {\lambda_{t}}{\sigma_{t}} + \frac{k}{\gamma}\beta_{t} \rho \frac {h_{y}}{h}\) is uniformly bounded by some \(c>0\). Hence by Lemma 5.3, we have
Analogously, we obtain that \(\int_{0}^{T} \operatorname{E}[ \hat{m}_{t}^{2} \hat{X}_{t}^{2} (k\sqrt{1- \rho^{2}}\beta_{t} \frac {h_{y}}{h})^{2}] \,\mathrm{d} t <\infty\). From this and Lemma 5.5, we conclude that \(Z^{\hat{\pi},\hat{c}}\) is an \(L^{2}\)-martingale. □
Proof of Proposition 6.4
For any fixed \(\kappa > c + \varrho\), define a metric \(d\) equivalent to \(\|{\,\cdot \,}\|_{\infty}\) by \(d(X,Y):=\mathop {\mathrm {ess}\,\mathrm {sup}}_{\,\mathrm{d} t \otimes \,\mathrm{d} \mathrm{P}} e^{-\kappa (T-t)} |X_{t} - Y_{t}|\). Then \((A,d)\) is a complete metric space. By definition, \(|X_{s}-Y_{s}| \leq e^{\kappa (T-s)} d(X,Y) \,\mathrm{d} t \otimes \,\mathrm{d}\mathrm{P}\)-a.e., so
and we conclude that \(d(SX,SY) \leq \frac {c}{\kappa- \varrho} d(X,Y)\), where \(\frac {c}{\kappa- \varrho}<1\). Hence \(S\) is a contraction on \((A,d)\). Thus by Banach’s fixed point theorem, there is a unique \(X\in A\) with \(S X = X\), and we have \(d(X_{(n)},X) \leq ( \frac {c}{\kappa-\varrho})^{n} d(X_{(0)},X)\) for all \(n\in \mathbb{N}\). Hence it follows that
and thus \(\|X_{(n)}-X\|_{\infty}\le e^{\kappa T} (\|X_{(0)}\|_{\infty}+ \|X\|_{\infty}) (\frac {c}{\kappa - \varrho} )^{n}\), for every \(n\in \mathbb{N}\) and every choice of \(\kappa>c+\varrho\). Setting \(\kappa=\frac{n+T\varrho}{T}\) for \(n>cT\), we obtain the asserted error bound. □
Appendix B: Stochastic Gronwall inequality
This appendix provides a ramification of the stochastic Gronwall–Bellman inequality which is required for the proofs in this article. Related results can be found in [17, 1, 36]. We work on a general probability space \((\varOmega, \mathcal {F},\mathrm{P})\) that is endowed with a filtration \((\mathcal {F}_{t})_{t \geq 0}\) that is right-continuous and complete.
Proposition B.1
Suppose \(A=(A_{t})_{t\in[0,T]}\) is bounded and progressively measurable, \(Z \in L^{p}(\mathrm{P})\) and \(B=(B_{t})_{t\in[0,T]}\) is a progressively measurable process in \(L^{p}(\,\mathrm{d} t \otimes \,\mathrm{d}\mathrm{P})\) for some \(p>1\). Moreover, let \(X = (X_{t})_{t \in [0,T]}\) be right-continuous and adapted with \(\operatorname{E}[\sup_{t\in [0,T]} |X_{t}|]<\infty\). If
for every stopping time \(\tau\) and \(X_{T} \geq Z\), then
Proof
We set
Since \(A\) is bounded above, \(Z\in L^{p}(\mathrm{P})\) and \(B \in L^{p}(\,\mathrm{d} t \otimes \,\mathrm{d}\mathrm{P})\), it follows from Doob’s \(L^{p}\)-inequality that \(\operatorname{E}[\sup_{t\in [0,T]} |M_{t}|^{p}]<\infty\). In particular, \(M\) is well defined as a uniformly integrable martingale. Now set
Since \(A\) is bounded below, we have \(\operatorname{E}[\sup_{t\in[0,T]}|Y_{t}|^{p}]<\infty\), and integration by parts yields
where \(N_{t}:=\int_{0}^{t} e^{-\int_{0}^{s} A_{u}\,\mathrm{d} u}\,\mathrm{d} M_{s}\) is a uniformly integrable martingale. For an arbitrary stopping time \(\tau\), we obtain
so that
Since \((1_{\{\tau >t \}}(N_{t} - N_{\tau}))_{s\in[t,T]}\) is a martingale, it follows that
We set \(\Delta_{t}:=X_{t} -Y_{t}\) and obtain \(\Delta_{T} = X_{T}-Z \ge 0\) and \(\operatorname{E}[\sup_{t\in[0,T]}|\Delta_{t}|]<\infty\). Moreover, (B.1) and (B.2) imply that for any stopping time \(\tau\),
Thus Proposition C.2 in [40] applies to yield \(\Delta_{t} \geq 0\) for all \(t\in[0,T]\) a.s., i.e.,
□
Appendix C: Some facts on parabolic partial differential equations
This appendix collects the relevant results on linear and semilinear parabolic partial differential equations that are used in this article. Following [29], we first introduce the Hölder spaces \(H^{r/2,r}([0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^{d})\) for \(r\in \mathbb{R}_{+}\). For a continuous function \(u: [0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d} \to \mathbb{R}, (t,x) \mapsto u(t,x)\), and \(q\in(0,1)\), we define the Hölder coefficient \(\langle u\rangle^{q}_{x}\) in space via
and the Hölder coefficient \(\langle u\rangle^{q}_{t}\) in time via
The space \(H^{r/2,r}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d})\) consists of all functions \(u: [0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d}\to \mathbb{R}\) that are continuous along with all derivatives \(D^{\alpha}_{t} D^{\beta}_{x} u\) with “order” \(2|\alpha| + |\beta| \le r\) and satisfy \(\|u\|_{H}^{r/2,r} < \infty\). Here the norm \(\|u\|_{H}^{r/2,r}\) of \(u\) is given by
where the mixed space-time Hölder coefficient \(\langle u\rangle^{r/2,r}_{\bullet}\) of \(u\) is given by
Thus \(\|u\|_{H}^{r/2,r}\) sums up the \(L^{\infty}\)-norms of all relevant derivatives plus the Hölder coefficients of the highest-order derivatives. Analogously, for \(r\in \mathbb{R}_{+}\), the space \(H^{r}(\mathbb{R}^{d})\) is defined as the collection of all \(\lfloor r \rfloor\) times continuously differentiable functions \(u: \mathbb{R}^{d} \to \mathbb{R}\) with \(\|u\|_{H}^{r} < \infty\), whereFootnote 6
Linear Cauchy problem
Consider a linear second-order differential operator
where the coefficients \(a,b,c\) are defined on \([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d}\) and \((a_{i,j}(t,x))_{i,j}\) is a symmetric matrix for all \((t,x) \in [0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d}\). The main existence and uniqueness result for linear Cauchy problems in \(\mathbb{R}^{d}\), Theorem C.1 below, relies on the following conditions:
- \((\mathrm{P1})\) :
-
The operator \(L\) is uniformly parabolic, i.e., there exist \(0< c_{1}< c_{2}<\infty\) such that for every \((t,x)\in[0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d}\), we have
$$c_{1} |y|^{2} \leq { \sum_{i,j=1}^{d}} a_{ij}(t,x) y_{i} y_{j} \leq c_{2} |y|^{2} \quad \text{for all }y\in \mathbb{R}^{d}. $$ - \((\mathrm{P2})^{r}\) :
-
For all \(i,j=1,\dots,d\), we have \(a_{i,j}, b_{i}, c \in H^{r/2,r}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d})\).
Theorem C.1
Suppose \((\mathrm{P1})\) and \((\mathrm{P2})^{r}\) are satisfied with \(r\in \mathbb{R}_{+}\), \(r\notin \mathbb{N}\), and let \(\varphi\in H^{r+2}(\mathbb{R}^{d})\) and \(f\in H^{r/2,r}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d})\). Then there exists a unique function \(u\in H^{(r+2)/2,r+2}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d})\) such that
Moreover, \(u\) satisfies
where \(c>0\) is a global constant that is independent of \(\varphi\) and \(f\).
Proof
See [29, Theorem IV.5.1]. □
As a special case, we obtain the result we have used in the proof of Lemma 7.1.
Corollary C.2
Suppose that
- (C1):
-
\(a, b, c: \mathbb{R}\to \mathbb{R}\) are bounded and Lipschitz-continuous;
- (C2):
-
the function \(a\) has a bounded Lipschitz-continuous derivative and satisfies \(\inf_{y \in \mathbb{R}} a (y) >0\);
- (\(\mathrm{C3}^{\prime}\)):
-
\(\hat{\varepsilon}\in H^{r+2}(\mathbb{R})\) for some \(r \in (0,1)\).
Then for each bounded and Lipschitz-continuous function \(f: [0,T] \times \mathbb{R}\to \mathbb{R}\), there exists a unique \(g\in C_{b}^{1,2}([0,T] \times \mathbb{R})\) that solves
Proof
Consider the second-order differential operator
By assumptions (C1) and (C2), the differential operator \(L\) satisfies (P1) and \((\mathrm{P2})^{r}\) for \(r \in (0,1)\). Moreover, \(f\) is in \(H^{r/2,r}([0,T] \times \mathbb{R})\) since it is Lipschitz-continuous. Hence Theorem C.1 yields \(u\in H^{(r+2)/2,r+2}([0,T] \times \mathbb{R})\) such that
Thus defining \(g\in C_{b}^{1,2}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R})\) by \(g(t,y) :=u(T-t, y)\), we obtain
□
Quasilinear Cauchy problem
Next consider the nonlinear differential operator
with principal part in divergence form. We set
We now state the conditions required for Theorem C.3.
-
(Q1)
For all \(t\in(0,T]\), \(x,p\in \mathbb{R}^{d}\) and \(u\in \mathbb{R}\), we have
$${ \sum_{i,j=1}^{d}} a_{ij}(t,x,u,p) y_{i} y_{j} \geq 0\quad \text{for all } y \in \mathbb{R}^{d}. $$ -
(Q2)
There exist \(b_{1}, b_{2} \geq 0\) such that for all \(t \in (0,T]\), \(x \in \mathbb{R}^{d}\) and \(u \in \mathbb{R}\), we have
$$A(t,x,u,0) \geq - b_{1} u^{2} - b_{2}. $$ -
(Q3)
The functions \(a\) and \(a_{i}\) are continuous, and \(a_{i}\) is differentiable with respect to \(x\), \(u\) and \(p\). Moreover, there exist \(c_{1}, c_{2} >0\) such that for all tuples \(v =(t,x,u,p)\) in \([0,T]\times \mathbb{R}^{d} \times \mathbb{R}\times \mathbb{R}^{d}\), we have
$$c_{1}|y|^{2} \leq { \sum_{i,j=1}^{n}} a_{ij}(v) y_{i} y_{j} \leq c_{2} |y|^{2}\quad \text{for all } y\in \mathbb{R}^{d} $$and, with \(a_{ij}\) given by (C.1),
- \((\mathrm{Q4})^{\beta}\) :
-
There exists \(\beta\in(0,1)\) such that for all compact sets \(K\subset \mathbb{R}\), \(\bar{K} \subset \mathbb{R}^{d}\), the functions
$$a_{i}, a, a_{ij}, \frac{\partial a_{i}}{\partial u}, \frac{\partial a_{i}}{\partial x_{i}}: [0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^{d} \times K \times \bar{K} \to \mathbb{R}$$are Hölder-continuous in \(t,x,u\) and \(p\) with exponents \(\beta/2\), \(\beta\), \(\beta\) and \(\beta\), respectively.
Here we say that \(f:[0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^{d} \times K \times \bar{K} \to \mathbb{R}, z= (z^{1},z^{2}, z^{3}, z^{4})\mapsto f(z)\) is \(\beta\)-Hölder-continuous in \(z^{i}\) if
Theorem C.3
Suppose \(\psi_{0}\) is in \(H^{2+\beta}(\mathbb{R}^{d})\) and (Q1), (Q2), (Q3) and (Q4)β are satisfied for some \(\beta \in (0, 1)\). Then there exists a solution \(u \in H^{(2+ \beta)/2, 2+ \beta}([0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^{d})\) of the Cauchy problem
Proof
See [29, Theorem V.8.1]. □
In the proof of Theorem 6.10, we require the following ramification of this result.
Corollary C.4
Suppose that
- (C1):
-
\(a, b, c: \mathbb{R}\to \mathbb{R}\) are bounded and Lipschitz-continuous;
- (C2):
-
the function \(a\) has a bounded Lipschitz-continuous derivative and satisfies \(\inf_{y \in \mathbb{R}} a (y) >0\);
- (\(\mathrm{C3}^{\prime}\)):
-
\(\hat{\varepsilon}\in H^{r+2}(\mathbb{R})\) for some \(r \in (0,1)\);
and let \(f\in C^{1}_{b}(\mathbb{R})\). Then the semilinear PDE
has a solution \(g\in C_{b}^{1,2}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R})\).
Proof
After setting \(a_{1}(t,x,u,p):=p a(x)\) and
we can represent the relevant differential operator as
Hence if \(u \in C_{b}^{1,2}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R})\) solves \(Lu=0\), \(u(0,\cdot)=\hat{\varepsilon}\), then \(g(t,x):=u(T-t,x)\) defines a member of \(C_{b}^{1,2}([0,T]\times \mathbb{R})\) that satisfies
We now verify the assumptions of Theorem C.3 for \(L\). Note that
so (Q1) holds since
Next observe that
Thus (Q2) is satisfied since
with \(b_{1}:=\|c\|_{\infty}\) and \(b_{2}:=\|c\|_{\infty}+ \|f\|_{\infty}\). To check (Q3), note that by (C1) and (C2), the functions \(a_{1}\) and \(\bar{a}\) are continuous, and \(a_{1}\) is differentiable; moreover,
for all \(t \in [0,T]\) and \(x,u,p,y \in \mathbb{R}\). For all \(v = (t,x,u,p) \in [0,T] \times \mathbb{R}\times \mathbb{R}\times \mathbb{R}\), we further have
since \(a,b,c,f\) and \(a'\) are bounded. Thus (Q3) holds with
and \(c_{1}:=\inf_{x \in \mathbb{R}} a(x) >0\). Finally, for any compact set \(K \subset \mathbb{R}\), the functions
restricted to \([0,T] \times \mathbb{R}\times K \times K\) are Lipschitz-continuous in \(x\), \(u\) and \(p\), because \(a\), \(a'\), \(b\), \(c\) and \(f\) are bounded and Lipschitz by (C1), (C2) and since \(f \in C_{b}^{1}(\mathbb{R})\). Hence (Q4)\(^{\frac{1}{2}}\) holds as well. Thus by Theorem C.3, the Cauchy problem
has a solution \(u \in H^{5/4,5/2}([0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^{d}) \subset C_{b}^{1,2} ([0,T] \times \mathbb{R}^{d})\). Uniqueness follows from standard BSDE arguments; see e.g. [20, Proposition 4.3]. □
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Kraft, H., Seiferling, T. & Seifried, F.T. Optimal consumption and investment with Epstein–Zin recursive utility. Finance Stoch 21, 187–226 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-016-0316-0
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-016-0316-0
Keywords
- Consumption-portfolio choice
- Asset pricing
- Stochastic differential utility
- Incomplete markets
- Fixed point approach
- FBSDE