Abstract
We study the pricing and hedging of derivative securities with uncertainty about the volatility of the underlying asset. Rather than taking all models from a prespecified class equally seriously, we penalise less plausible ones based on their “distance” to a reference local volatility model. In the limit for small uncertainty aversion, this leads to explicit formulas for prices and hedging strategies in terms of the security’s cash gamma.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
This terminology stems from the literature on robust control [33] and also from the robust representation of convex risk measures (see e.g. [25, Sect. 5.2]). Note that the penalty is not imposed on the agent, but on her fictitious adversary who minimises over \(P\). Hence, the penalty in (1.1) is added and not subtracted.
A similar penalty has been used by [5] in the context of local volatility calibration with prior beliefs.
Our results can be formally linked to the UVM with a random, time-dependent volatility band depending on the option’s cash gamma and the agent’s uncertainty aversion; cf. Remark 3.7. Note that the cash gamma also plays a crucial role in the asymptotic analysis of other frictions such as discrete rebalancing [9], transaction costs [64], price impact [51], or jumps [13].
Specifically, the payoff is the Black–Scholes value of a standard put option with strike 100 and maturity 1 day.
As the option payoff is convex, this spread is simply the difference between the Black–Scholes values of the “smooth put” corresponding to the two endpoints of the volatility band.
Here and in the following, subscripts on functions denote the corresponding partial derivatives.
The strategy adjustment may become dependent on risk aversion for other penalty functionals; see the discussion following Theorem 3.4.
A rigorous verification of these results would proceed along the same lines as for the simpler benchmark case discussed here. In order not to drown the ideas in further technicalities resulting from even more state variables, regularity conditions, etc., we do not pursue this here.
The same formula is obtained—mutatis mutandis—for exotics of Asian, lookback or barrier type, after adding the appropriate state variables to the reference cash gamma.
Under each \(P\), the stochastic integrals of sufficiently integrable, progressively measurable integrands against Itô process integrators are constructed as \(\mathbb{F}\)-progressively measurable stochastic processes with \(P\)-a.s. continuous paths; see the discussion before Lemma 4.3.3 in Stroock and Varadhan [63].
Since \(\mathfrak{P}(\theta ,\sigma )\) may contain more than one measure, we also have to allow “nature” to choose a specific measure.
The penalty functional in the sense of the criterion (1.1) is \(\alpha (P) = E^{P} [ \mathfrak{a}(\sigma^{P}) ]\), where \(\sigma^{P}\) is the volatility of returns of \(S\) under \(P\).
Recall from footnote 2 that \(\mathfrak{a}\) penalises the fictitious adversary (“nature”) and not the agent.
Notably, [5] show that penalty functionals of this form can arise as the continuous-time limit of the relative entropy in a discrete-time approximation.
Using \(U'(y_{0})\) instead of \(U'(Y_{t})\) would yield the same expansion for \(v(\psi )\) as in Theorem 3.4 and, formally and at the leading order, the same almost optimal strategies and volatilities. This is because in the asymptotic limit for small uncertainty aversion, the P&L process converges to a constant.
In the context of robust portfolio choice, Maenhout [50] also observes that some modification of the standard (non wealth-dependent) entropic penalty is reasonable to avoid that the agent’s uncertainty aversion wears off as her wealth rises, and tackles this effect by directly modifying the HJBI equation.
Here, we assume that all relevant partial derivatives exist; precise conditions are given in Assumption 3.2.
Hölder-continuity uniformly on \((0,T)\times (K ^{-1},K)\) suffices for this step.
Strictly speaking, \(\theta^{\psi }\) and \(\sigma^{\psi }\) have to be defined for every \(\omega \in \varOmega \), even those for which \(S\) or \(Y\) exceeds the bounds (3.1). Outside these bounds, however, the functions \(\bar{V}_{s}\), \(\widetilde{\theta }\), \(\bar{\sigma }\), \(\widetilde{\sigma }\) are not defined. As we only consider measures \(P\) such that (3.1) holds, we do not make explicit the corresponding straightforward adjustments, which would only hamper readability.
Mutatis mutandis, the threshold 1 in the definition of the stopping time \(\tau \) can be replaced by any other constant. The same modification also appears in the asymptotic analysis of models with transaction costs [44].
A sufficient condition for \(\widetilde{w}_{sy} = 0\) is that \(f''(t,s,y;\varsigma )\) does not depend on \(y\).
A second-order expansion for the ask price can also be obtained, but does not offer much additional insight.
This symmetry generally breaks down for the second-order term \(\widehat{w}\); cf. the corresponding source term (3.5). Hence, for a second-order expansion of the indifference bid price, we have to use the \(\widehat{w}\) corresponding to the negative of the option.
This specification is a particular case of the general “random \(G\)-expectation” [56].
For example, if \(N\) is integrable under \(P^{\theta ,\sigma }\) for each \((\theta ,\sigma ) \in \mathcal{A} \times \mathcal{V}\), then \(v\) is a well-defined number in the extended real line \([-\infty ,+\infty ]\).
We obtain the same results if we interchange the order of the infimum and the supremum. In the language of two-player, zero-sum stochastic differential games, this indicates that the game “has a value”.
This covers most of the specific choices that are dealt with in the following subsections, except for additional state variables needed for some exotic options in Sect. 4.2. To explain the general procedure, we first focus here on the easiest case with just two state variables, the stock price \(S\) and the P&L process \(Y\).
Note that this hedge \(\bar{\varDelta }\) reflects the option’s sensitivity to price moves in the underlying both directly through \(S\) and indirectly through the additional state variable \(A\).
Portfolios including exotic options can be treated along the same lines; we do not pursue this here to ease notation.
That is, the local volatility model is calibrated to the observed market prices of the liquid options at time 0.
Portfolios of barrier options as in [4] or other exotics can be treated along the same lines, but require a more extensive notation.
For instance, if \(\theta \) is of finite variation, then the stochastic integral can be defined pathwise via the integration by parts formula.
Unlike [14], we disregard bid-ask spreads for the liquidly traded options.
A Mathematica file containing these calculations is available from the authors upon request.
References
Acciaio, B., Beiglböck, M., Penkner, F., Schachermayer, W.: A model-free version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing and the super-replication theorem. Math. Finance 26, 233–251 (2016)
Ahn, H., Muni, A., Swindle, G.: Misspecified asset price models and robust hedging strategies. Appl. Math. Finance 4, 21–36 (1997)
Ahn, H., Muni, A., Swindle, G.: Optimal hedging strategies for misspecified asset price models. Appl. Math. Finance 6, 197–208 (1999)
Avellaneda, M., Buff, R.: Combinatorial implications of nonlinear uncertain volatility models: the case of barrier options. Appl. Math. Finance 6, 1–18 (1999)
Avellaneda, M., Friedman, C., Holmes, R., Samperi, D.: Calibrating volatility surfaces via relative-entropy minimization. Appl. Math. Finance 4, 37–64 (1997)
Avellaneda, M., Levy, A., Parás, A.: Pricing and hedging derivative securities in markets with uncertain volatilities. Appl. Math. Finance 2, 73–88 (1995)
Avellaneda, M., Parás, A.: Managing the volatility risk of portfolios of derivative securities: the Lagrangian uncertain volatility model. Appl. Math. Finance 3, 21–52 (1996)
Beiglböck, M., Henry-Labordère, P., Penkner, F.: Model-independent bounds for option prices—a mass transport approach. Finance Stoch. 17, 477–501 (2013)
Bertsimas, D., Kogan, L., Lo, A.: When is time continuous? J. Financ. Econ. 55, 173–204 (2000)
Biagini, S., Bouchard, B., Kardaras, C., Nutz, M.: Robust fundamental theorem for continuous processes. Math. Finance (2016). doi:10.1111/mafi.12110/full
Bouchard, B., Nutz, M.: Arbitrage and duality in nondominated discrete-time models. Ann. Appl. Probab. 25, 823–859 (2015)
Brown, H., Hobson, D., Rogers, L.C.G.: Robust hedging of barrier options. Math. Finance 11, 285–314 (2001)
Černý, A., Denkl, S., Kallsen, J.: Hedging in Lévy models and the time step equivalent of jumps. Preprint (2013). Available online at http://arxiv.org/abs/1309.7833
Cont, R.: Model uncertainty and its impact on the pricing of derivative instruments. Math. Finance 16, 519–547 (2006)
Cox, A., Obłój, J.: Robust hedging of double touch barrier options. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 2, 141–182 (2011)
Cox, A., Obłój, J.: Robust pricing and hedging of double no-touch options. Finance Stoch. 15, 573–605 (2011)
Davis, M.: Martingale methods in stochastic control. In: Kohlmann, M., Vogel, W. (eds.) Stochastic Control and Stochastic Differential Systems. Lecture Notes in Control and Information Sciences, vol. 16, pp. 85–117. Springer, Berlin (1979)
Dellacherie, C., Meyer, P.-A.: Probabilities and Potential. Mathematics Studies, vol. 29. North-Holland, Amsterdam (1978)
Denis, L., Martini, C.: A theoretical framework for the pricing of contingent claims in the presence of model uncertainty. Ann. Appl. Probab. 16, 827–852 (2006)
Dolinsky, Y., Soner, H.M.: Martingale optimal transport and robust hedging in continuous time. Probab. Theory Relat. Fields 160, 391–427 (2014)
Dumas, B., Fleming, J., Whaley, R.: Implied volatility functions: empirical tests. J. Finance 53, 2059–2106 (1998)
Dupire, B.: Pricing with a smile. Risk 7(1), 18–20 (1994)
Fleming, W., Hernández-Hernández, D.: On the value of stochastic differential games. Commun. Stoch. Anal. 5, 341–351 (2011)
Fleming, W., Souganidis, P.: On the existence of value functions of two-player, zero-sum stochastic differential games. Indiana Univ. Math. J. 38, 293–314 (1989)
Föllmer, H., Schied, A.: Probabilistic aspects of finance. Bernoulli 19, 1306–1326 (2013)
Fouque, J.-P., Ren, B.: Approximation for option prices under uncertain volatility. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 5, 260–383 (2014)
Frey, R.: Superreplication in stochastic volatility models and optimal stopping. Finance Stoch. 4, 161–187 (2000)
Friedman, A.: Partial Differential Equations of Parabolic Type. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs (1964)
Galichon, A., Henry-Labordère, P., Touzi, N.: A stochastic control approach to no-arbitrage bounds given marginals, with an application to lookback options. Ann. Appl. Probab. 24, 312–336 (2014)
Gatheral, J.: The Volatility Surface: A Practitioner’s Guide. Wiley, Hoboken (2006)
Gilboa, I., Schmeidler, D.: Maxmin expected utility with non-unique prior. J. Math. Econ. 18, 141–153 (1989)
Hansen, L., Sargent, T.: Robust control and model uncertainty. Am. Econ. Rev. 91(2), 60–66 (2001)
Hansen, L., Sargent, T.: Robustness. Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton (2007)
Hayashi, T., Mykland, P.: Evaluating hedging errors: an asymptotic approach. Math. Finance 15, 309–343 (2005)
Herrmann, S., Muhle-Karbe, J.: Model uncertainty, dynamic recalibration, and the emergence of delta-vega hedging. Preprint (2015). Available online at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2694718
Hobson, D.: Robust hedging of the lookback option. Finance Stoch. 2, 329–347 (1998)
Hobson, D.: Volatility misspecification, option pricing and superreplication via coupling. Ann. Appl. Probab. 8, 193–205 (1998)
Hobson, D.: The Skorokhod embedding problem and model-independent bounds for option prices. In: Carmona, R., et al. (eds.) Paris–Princeton Lectures on Mathematical Finance 2010. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, vol. 2003, pp. 267–318. Springer, Berlin (2011)
Hobson, D., Klimmek, M.: Model-independent hedging strategies for variance swaps. Finance Stoch. 16, 611–649 (2012)
Hobson, D., Klimmek, M.: Robust price bounds for the forward starting straddle. Finance Stoch. 19, 189–214 (2015)
Hobson, D., Neuberger, A.: Robust bounds for forward start options. Math. Finance 22, 31–56 (2012)
Hou, Z., Obłój, J.: On robust pricing-hedging duality in continuous time. Preprint (2015). Available online at http://arxiv.org/abs/1503.02822
Kallenberg, O.: Foundations of Modern Probability, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin (2002)
Kallsen, J., Li, S.: Portfolio optimization under small transaction costs: a convex duality approach. Preprint (2013). Available online at http://arxiv.org/abs/1309.3479
Kallsen, J., Muhle-Karbe, J.: Option pricing and hedging with small transaction costs. Math. Finance 25, 702–723 (2015)
Karatzas, I., Shreve, S.: Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin (1998)
El Karoui, N., Jeanblanc-Picqué, M., Shreve, S.: Robustness of the Black and Scholes formula. Math. Finance 8, 93–126 (1998)
Lyons, T.: Uncertain volatility and the risk-free synthesis of derivatives. Appl. Math. Finance 2, 117–133 (1995)
Maccheroni, F., Marinacci, M., Rustichini, A.: Ambiguity aversion, robustness, and the variational representation of preferences. Econometrica 74, 1447–1498 (2006)
Maenhout, P.: Robust portfolio rules and asset pricing. Rev. Financ. Stud. 17, 951–983 (2004)
Moreau, L., Muhle-Karbe, J., Soner, H.M.: Trading with small price impact. Math. Finance (2016). doi:10.1111/mafi.12098/full
Mykland, P.: Conservative delta hedging. Ann. Appl. Probab. 10, 664–683 (2000)
Mykland, P.: Financial options and statistical prediction intervals. Ann. Stat. 31, 1413–1438 (2003)
Mykland, P.: The interpolation of options. Finance Stoch. 7, 417–432 (2003)
Neufeld, A., Nutz, M.: Superreplication under volatility uncertainty for measurable claims. Electron. J. Probab. 18, 1–14 (2013)
Nutz, M.: Random \(G\)-expectations. Ann. Appl. Probab. 23, 1755–1777 (2013)
Nutz, M.: Superreplication under model uncertainty in discrete time. Finance Stoch. 18, 791–803 (2014)
Pham, T., Zhang, J.: Two person zero-sum game in weak formulation and path dependent Bellman–Isaacs equation. SIAM J. Control Optim. 52, 2090–2121 (2014)
Possamaï, D., Royer, G., Touzi, N.: On the robust superhedging of measurable claims. Electron. Commun. Probab. 18(95), 1–13 (2013)
Rogers, L.C.G., Williams, D.: Diffusions, Markov Processes, and Martingales, vol. 2: Itô Calculus, 2nd edn. Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge (2000)
Seifried, F.: Optimal investment for worst-case crash scenarios: a martingale approach. Math. Oper. Res. 35, 559–579 (2010)
Stebegg, F.: Model-independent pricing of Asian options via optimal martingale transport. Preprint (2014). Available online at http://arxiv.org/abs/1412.1429
Stroock, D., Varadhan, S.R.S.: Multidimensional Diffusion Processes. Springer, Berlin (1979)
Whalley, A., Wilmott, P.: An asymptotic analysis of an optimal hedging model for option pricing with transaction costs. Math. Finance 7, 307–324 (1997)
Acknowledgements
The authors thank Ibrahim Ekren, Paolo Guasoni, Martin Herdegen, David Hobson, Jan Kallsen, Ariel Neufeld, Marcel Nutz, Oleg Reichmann, Martin Schweizer and H. Mete Soner for fruitful discussions, and two referees and an Associate Editor for helpful comments.
The first author gratefully acknowledges financial support by the Swiss Finance Institute.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix A: Calculus
The following result is an extension of the implicit function theorem that allows the defining function to depend on a parameter. In particular, it provides parameter-independent bounds for the first and second derivatives of the implicitly defined functions.
Lemma A.1
Let \(\varLambda \neq \emptyset \) be a set, and \(U\), \(V\) open subsets of ℝ. For each \(\lambda \in \varLambda \), let \(F_{\lambda }: U \times V \to \mathbb{R}\) and \(y_{\lambda }: U \to V\) be twice continuously differentiable functions with
If there are constants \(M_{0} > 1\) and \(M_{1} \geq 0\) such that for each \(\lambda \in \varLambda \) and all \((x,y) \in U \times V\),
then there is a constant \(\widetilde{M} > 0\) such that for all \(\lambda \in \varLambda \) and \(x\in U\),
Moreover, if \(\frac{\partial^{2} F_{\lambda }}{\partial y^{2}} \equiv 0\), then for all \(\lambda \in \varLambda \) and \(x\in U\),
Proof
Taking the derivative of (A.1) with respect to \(x\) yields
Solving this for \(y_{\lambda }'(x)\) and using the bounds (A.2) then gives
Taking the derivative in (A.3), we obtain for all \(x\in U\) that
Again, solving for \(y_{\lambda }''(x)\) and using the bounds (A.2) and (A.4) gives
for some sufficiently large constant \(\overline{M}\). Finally, if \(\frac{\partial^{2} F_{\lambda }}{\partial y^{2}} \equiv 0\), then it is easily seen that the quadratic term in (A.5) vanishes. □
Appendix B: Stochastic differential equations
Fix an abstract filtered probability space \((\varOmega , \mathcal{F}, \mathbb{F}= (\mathcal{F}_{t})_{t\geq 0}, P)\) carrying an \(r\)-dimensional Brownian motion \(W = (W^{1}_{t},\ldots , W^{r} _{t})_{t\geq 0}\). The goal of this section is to prove the existence of solutions for a class of stochastic differential equations (SDEs) whose coefficients change at a stopping time. More precisely, we consider SDEs of the form
where \(\xi \) is an \(\mathbb{R}^{d}\)-valued \(\mathcal{F}_{0}\)-measurable random vector, \(X = (X^{1}_{t},\ldots ,X^{d}_{t})_{t\geq 0}\) is a continuous semimartingale in \(\mathbb{R}^{d}\), and
Here, \(\tau \) is a stopping time for the filtration induced by the canonical process on \(C(\mathbb{R}_{+};\mathbb{R}^{d})\), \(\sigma^{(1)}\), \(b ^{(1)}\) are functions on \(\mathbb{R}_{+}\times C(\mathbb{R}_{+}; \mathbb{R}^{d})\) that are progressive for the same filtration, and \(\sigma^{(2)},b^{(2)}\) are measurable functions on \(\mathbb{R}_{+} \times \mathbb{R}^{d}\); all codomains are understood to be of suitable dimension.
First of all, note that we cannot apply general existence results directly to the coefficients \(\sigma \) and \(b\) since the stopping time \(\tau \) is typically not a continuous function on \(C(\mathbb{R}_{+}; \mathbb{R}^{d})\). However, existence for this type of SDE is of course expected, provided that solutions exist for both sets of coefficients separately. The obvious idea is to solve the SDE for the first set of coefficients, stop the solution at \(\tau \), and solve from there the SDE with the second set of coefficients. This can be made precise as follows.
Theorem B.1
Suppose that the process \(X^{(1)}\) on \((\varOmega ,\mathcal{F}, \mathbb{F},P)\) satisfies
Moreover, assume that there is a constant \(K > 0\) such that for all \(t, t' \geq 0\) and \(x, x' \in \mathbb{R}^{d}\),
where \(\vert \cdot \vert \) denotes the Euclidean norm in the suitable dimension. Then there is a continuous, \(\mathbb{F}\)-adapted, \(\mathbb{R}^{d}\)-valued process \(X\) satisfying (B.1).
Proof
The solution prior to time \(\hat{\tau }:= \tau (X^{(1)})\) is already given. To construct the part of the solution after time \(\hat{\tau }\), consider the time-shifted filtration \(\widehat{\mathbb{F}}= ( \widehat{\mathcal{F}}_{t})_{t \geq 0}\) defined by \(\widehat{\mathcal{F}}_{t} = \mathcal{F}_{\hat{\tau }+ t}\) and the time-shifted \((\widehat{\mathbb{F}},P)\)-Brownian motion \(\widehat{W} = (\widehat{W}_{t})_{t \geq 0}\) defined by \(\widehat{W}_{t} := W_{ \hat{\tau }+ t} - W_{\hat{\tau }}\). By our assumptions (B.4) and (B.5), the coefficients of the SDE
fulfil the standard Lipschitz and linear growth assumptions that guarantee the existence of a \(P\)-a.s. unique strong solution for any \(\widehat{\mathcal{F}}_{0}\)-measurable random vector \(\zeta \) in \(\mathbb{R}^{d+1}\). In particular, there exists an \(\widehat{\mathbb{F}}\)-progressive process \(\widehat{Y} = (\widehat{X}, \widehat{A})\) for the initial condition \(\zeta := (X^{(1)}_{ \hat{\tau }},\hat{\tau })\). Clearly, \(\widehat{A}_{t} = \hat{\tau }+ t\) plays the role of the shifted time variable. A simple time change now yields that \(X^{(2)}_{t} := \widehat{X}_{t-\hat{\tau }} \mathbf{1} _{\lbrace t \geq \hat{\tau }\rbrace }\) is \(\mathbb{F}\)-progressive and satisfies
Finally, we verify that the process \(X_{t} := X^{(1)}_{t} \mathbf{1} _{\lbrace t < \hat{\tau }\rbrace } + X^{(2)}_{t}\mathbf{1}_{\lbrace t \geq \hat{\tau }\rbrace }\) is a solution to the original SDE (B.1). As \(X^{(2)}_{\hat{\tau }} = X^{(1)}_{\hat{\tau }}\),
Plugging in (B.3) and (B.6) gives
As \(X^{(1)}_{s} = X_{s}\) on \(\lbrace s \leq \hat{\tau }\rbrace \), Galmarino’s test implies that \(\hat{\tau }= \tau (X^{(1)}) = \tau (X)\). Moreover, since \(\sigma^{(1)}\) is progressive, \(\sigma^{(1)}(s,X^{(1)})\) only depends on the path of \(X^{(1)}\) up to time \(s\). Using also the definition of \(\sigma \) in (B.2), we obtain
Using this and the analogous statement for the drift coefficients, we see from (B.7) that \(X\) is a solution to (B.1). □
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Herrmann, S., Muhle-Karbe, J. & Seifried, F.T. Hedging with small uncertainty aversion. Finance Stoch 21, 1–64 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-016-0309-z
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-016-0309-z