Abstract
We price a contingent claim liability (claim for short) using a utility indifference argument. We consider an agent with exponential utility, who invests in a stock and a money market account with the goal of maximizing the utility of his investment at the final time T in the presence of a proportional transaction cost ε>0 in two cases: with and without a claim. Using the heuristic computations of Whalley and Wilmott (Math. Finance 7:307–324, 1997), under suitable technical conditions, we provide a rigorous derivation of the asymptotic expansion of the value function in powers of \(\varepsilon^{\frac{1}{3}}\) in both cases with and without a claim. Additionally, using the utility indifference method, we derive the price of the claim at the leading order of \(\varepsilon^{\frac{2}{3}}\). In both cases, we also obtain a “nearly optimal” strategy, whose expected utility asymptotically matches the leading terms of the value function. We also present an example of how this methodology can be used to price more exotic barrier-type contingent claims.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
We thank an anonymous referee for pointing out this example.
References
Barles, G., Soner, H.M.: Option pricing with transaction costs and a nonlinear Black–Scholes equation. Finance Stoch. 2, 369–397 (1998)
Bichuch, M.: Asymptotic analysis for optimal investment in finite time with transaction costs. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 3, 433–458 (2012)
Bichuch, M., Shreve, S.: Utility maximization trading two futures with transaction costs. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 4, 26–85 (2013)
Bouchard, B.: Option pricing via utility maximization in the presence of transaction costs: an asymptotic analysis. Preprint (2000). Available at www.ceremade.dauphine.fr/CMD/2000-6.ps
Bouchard, B., Touzi, N.: Explicit solution of the multi-variable super-replication problem under transaction costs. Ann. Appl. Probab. 10, 685–708 (2000)
Boyle, P.P., Vorst, T.: Option replication in discrete time with transaction costs. J. Finance 47, 272–293 (1992)
Burdzy, K., Kang, W., Ramanan, K.: The Skorokhod problem in a time-dependent interval. Stoch. Process. Appl. 119, 428–452 (2009)
Clewlow, L., Hodges, S.D.: Optimal delta-hedging under transactions costs. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 21, 1353–1376 (1997)
Constantinides, G., Zariphopoulou, T.: Bounds on prices of contingent claims in an intertemporal economy with proportional transaction costs and general preferences. Finance Stoch. 3, 345–369 (1999)
Constantinides, G., Zariphopoulou, T.: Bounds on derivative prices in an intertemporal setting with proportional transaction costs and multiple securities. Math. Finance 11, 331–346 (2001)
Crandall, M.G., Evans, L.C., Lions, P.-L.: Some properties of viscosity solutions of Hamilton–Jacobi equations. Trans. Am. Math. Soc. 282, 487–502 (1984)
Crandall, M.G., Ishii, H., Lions, P.L.: User’s guide to viscosity solutions of second order partial differential equations. AMS Bull. 1, 1–67 (1992)
Crandall, M.G., Lions, P.-L.: Viscosity solutions of Hamilton–Jacobi equations. Trans. Am. Math. Soc. 277, 1–42 (1983)
Cvitanić, J., Pham, H., Touzi, N.: A closed-form solution to the problem of super-replication under transaction costs. Finance Stoch. 3, 35–54 (1999)
Davis, M.H.A., Norman, A.: Portfolio selection with transaction costs. Math. Oper. Res. 15, 676–713 (1990)
Davis, M.H.A., Panas, V.G., Zariphopoulou, T.: European option pricing with transaction costs. SIAM J. Control 31, 470–493 (1993)
Delbaen, F., Kabanov, Yu., Valkeila, E.: Hedging under transaction costs in currency markets: a discrete-time model. Math. Finance 12, 45–61 (2002)
Dumas, B., Luciano, E.: An exact solution to a dynamic portfolio choice problem under transaction costs. J. Finance 46, 577–595 (1991)
Goodman, J., Ostrov, D.N.: An option to reduce transaction costs. SIAM J. Financ. Math. 2, 512–537 (2011)
Guasoni, P., Muhle-Karbe, J.: Long horizons, high risk-aversion, and endogenous spreads. Math. Finance (2013). doi:10.1111/mafi.12046
Hodges, S., Neuberger, A.: Option replication of contingent claims under transaction costs. Rev. Futures Mark. 8, 222–239 (1989)
Janeček, K., Shreve, S.: Asymptotic analysis for optimal investment and consumption with transaction costs. Finance Stoch. 8, 181–206 (2004)
Janeček, K., Shreve, S.: Futures trading with transaction costs. Ill. J. Math. 54, 1239–1284 (2010)
Kabanov, Yu., Last, G.: Hedging under transaction costs in currency markets. Math. Finance 12, 63–70 (2002)
Kabanov, Yu., Stricker, C.: Hedging of contingent claims under transaction costs. In: Sandmann, K., Schönbucher, P. (eds.) Advances in Finance and Stochastics. Essays in Honor of Dieter Sondermann, pp. 125–136. Springer, Berlin (2002)
Kallsen, J., Muhle-Karbe, J.: Option pricing and hedging with small transaction costs. Math. Finance (2013). doi:10.1111/mafi.12035
Koehl, P.F., Pham, H., Touzi, N.: Hedging in discrete time under transaction costs and continuous-time limit. J. Appl. Probab. 36, 163–178 (1999)
Koehl, P.F., Pham, H., Touzi, N.: On super-replication under transaction costs in general discrete time models. Theory Probab. Appl. 45, 783–788 (1999)
Leland, H.: Option pricing and replication with transaction costs. J. Finance 40, 1283–1301 (1985)
Levental, S., Skorohod, A.: On the possibility of hedging options in the presence of transaction costs. Ann. Appl. Probab. 7, 410–443 (1997)
Lott, K.: Ein Verfahren zur Replikation von Optionen unter Transaktionkosten in stetiger Zeit. Dissertation, Universität der Bundeswehr München, Institut für Mathematik und Datenverarbeitung (1993)
Magill, M.J.P., Constantinides, G.M.: Portfolio selection with transaction costs. J. Econ. Theory 13, 245–263 (1976)
Merton, R.: Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time case. J. Econ. Theory 3, 373–413 (1971). Erratum 6, 213–214 (1973)
Monoyios, M.: Option pricing with transaction costs using a Markov chain approximation. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 28, 889–913 (2004)
Muthuraman, K., Kumar, S.: Multidimensional portfolio optimization with proportional transaction costs. Math. Finance 16, 301–335 (2006)
Pham, H.: Continuous-Time Stochastic Control and Optimization with Financial Applications. Springer, Berlin (2009)
Possamaï, D., Soner, H.M., Touzi, N.: Homogenization and asymptotics for small transaction costs. Preprint (2012). Available at arXiv:1212.6275
Roper, M., Rutkowski, M.: On the relationship between the call price surface and the implied volatility surface close to expiry. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Finance 12, 427–441 (2009)
Schachermayer, W.: Optimal investment in incomplete markets when wealth may become negative. Ann. Appl. Probab. 11, 694–734 (2001)
Shreve, S., Soner, H.M.: Optimal investment and consumption with transaction costs. Ann. Appl. Probab. 4, 609–692 (1994)
Soner, H.M., Shreve, S., Cvitanić, J.: There is no nontrivial hedging portfolio for option pricing with transaction costs. Ann. Appl. Probab. 5, 327–355 (1995)
Whalley, A.E., Wilmott, P.: An asymptotic analysis of an optimal hedging model for option pricing under transaction costs. Math. Finance 7, 307–324 (1997)
Zakamouline, V.: Optimal hedging of option portfolios with transaction costs. Preprint (2006). Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=938934
Acknowledgements
The author acknowledges partial financial support from NSF grant DMS-0739195. The author wants to thank Peter Bank, Paolo Guasoni, Johannes Muhle-Karbe, Steven Shreve, and Stephan Sturm for helpful discussions.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
Proof of Lemma 4.1
Another way to express P 0(S,t) is to use the risk-neutral probability \(\tilde{\mathbb{P}}\) in the complete market with zero transaction costs. Then the Black–Scholes price P 0(S,t) of the contingent claim is
From Assumption 3.3, g is nonnegative, and it follows that P 0≥0. Moreover, for i≥2, we calculate
where by g (i) we mean the ith derivative. We conclude that
By Assumption 3.3, the bound in (A.1) is finite, and in a similar manner we conclude that on \(\mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\) the terms \(|{P_{0}-SP_{0_{S}}}|,~S^{2} |{P_{0_{SS}}}|\), \(|{S^{3}P_{0_{SSS}}}|\), and \(S^{4}|{P_{0_{SSSS}}}|\) are bounded by sup x>0|g(x)−g′(x)x|, sup x>0 x 2|g″(x)|, sup x>0|x 3 g (3)(x)|, and sup x>0 x 4|g (4)(x)|, respectively. We also calculate
and from the definition of \(H_{0}^{{ (j)}}\) in (2.8) conclude, both with and without claim, that \(|{S^{2}y_{S}^{{ (j)^{*}}}}|\) is bounded in \((S,t)\in \mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\), and \(|{S^{2}y_{S}^{{ (j)^{*}}}}|\ge\operatorname{e}^{-rT} \varepsilon_{1}\) there. The latter follows from Assumption 3.4. Similar calculations show that \(S^{3}y_{SS}^{{ (j)^{*}}}\) and \(S^{4}y_{SSS}^{{ (j)^{*}}}\) are also bounded in \((S,t)\in \mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\) for j=1,w. Moreover, from (2.7) we have that
From the boundedness of \(S^{2}P_{0_{SS}}\), \(S^{3}P_{0_{SSS}}\), and \(S^{4}P_{0_{SSSS}}\) on \(\mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\), the boundedness of \(S^{2}P_{0_{SSt}}\) also follows, and we conclude that \(S^{2}y_{St}^{{ (j)^{*}}}=S^{2}P_{0_{SSt}}-\frac{r\delta(\mu-r)}{\gamma \sigma ^{2}}\) is bounded in \((S,t)\in \mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\) in the cases both with and without liability. □
Proof of Lemma 6.5
From (6.7) we see that for \((S,Y,t)\in\overline{\mathbf{NT_{Y}^{(j)}}},~j=1,w\),
We use the estimates in Lemma 4.1 and Remark 6.1 to conclude that \(H_{4}^{{ (j)}}\) is bounded in \(\overline{\mathbf{NT_{Y}^{(j)}}}\), j=1,w. Similarly, using (6.10)–(6.13), Lemma 4.1, and Remark 6.1, we can show that the terms \(|{H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{YS}}}|\), \(|{Sy_{S}^{{ (j)^{*}}}H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{Y}}}|\), \(|{S^{2}y_{S}^{{ (j)^{*}}}H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{YS}}}|\), \(|{H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{t}}}\), \(|SH^{{ (j)}}_{4_{S}}|\), \(|{S^{2}H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{SS}}}|\), \(|{S^{2}y_{SS}^{{ (j)^{*}}}H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{Y}}}|\), and \(|{S^{2} (y_{S}^{{ (j)^{*}}} )^{2}H^{{ (j)}}_{4_{YY}}}|\) are all bounded in their respective domains in both cases j=1,w.
In the case j=1 of no claim, Remark 2.2 implies \((\frac{3\gamma^{2}S^{4}\sigma^{3} (y_{S}^{{(1)^{*}}} ) ^{2}}{2\delta^{2}} )^{\frac{2}{3}} = (\frac{3(\mu-r)^{2}}{2\sigma} )^{\frac{2}{3}}\). It follows that the solution to (3.4) in the case j=1 is given by (6.17) as claimed. Thus, \(H_{2}^{{(1)}}\) is bounded, and \(H_{2_{S}}^{{(1)}}=0\). We conclude that \(H_{3}^{{(1)^{\pm}}}(S,t)= \mp M^{{(1)}}(T-t)\mp M_{1}^{{(1)}}\), as defined in (6.5), will satisfy (6.18) with M (1) big enough and \(M_{1}^{{(1)}}\) given by (6.6).
We now concentrate on the case of holding a claim (j=w). We rewrite (3.4) as \(H_{2_{t}}^{(j)}+rSH_{2_{S}}^{(j)}+\frac {\sigma^{2}S^{2}}{2} H_{2_{SS}}^{(j)}=-f(S,t)\), where \(f(S,t)=\frac{1}{2} (\frac{3\gamma^{2}S^{4}\sigma^{3} ({y^{(w)^{*}}_{S}} )^{2}}{2\delta^{2}} )^{\frac{2}{3}}\) with the final condition \(H_{2}^{(w)}(S,T)=0\). Lemma 4.1 implies that on \(\mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\), both f(S,t) and Sf S (S,t) are bounded. Using the standard change of variables \(S=\operatorname{e}^{x}\), \(\tau=\frac {\sigma ^{2}}{2}(T-t)\), and \(k=\frac{2r}{\sigma^{2}}\), let \({\tilde{H}}_{2}(\tau ,x) := \operatorname{e}^{\frac{1}{2}(k-1)x+\frac{1}{4}(k+1)^{2}\tau-k\tau}H_{2}^{(w)}(S,t)\). We see that \({\tilde{H}}_{2}\) satisfies a nonhomogeneous heat equation, namely
with zero initial condition. The solution to this equation for \((\tau,x)\in[0,\frac{\sigma^{2}}{2}T]\times \mathbb{R}\) is
where \(\varPsi(x,t)=\frac{1}{\sqrt{4\pi t}}\exp{ (-\frac{x^{2}}{4t} )}\) is the heat kernel. From the boundedness of f it follows that \({\tilde{H}}_{2}(\tau ,x)=O (\operatorname{e}^{\frac{1}{2}(k-1)x} )\), and we conclude that \(H_{2}^{(w)}\) is bounded on \(\mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\). Moreover, \({\tilde{H}}_{2_{x}}\) also satisfies a nonhomogeneous heat equation, namely
with zero initial condition. Using the fact that \(\frac{\partial x}{\partial S} = \operatorname{e}^{-x}\), we calculate that
Let \(\tilde{\tilde{H}}_{2}=-\frac{1}{2}(k-1){\tilde{H}}_{2}+{\tilde{H}}_{2_{x}}\). Then \(H_{2_{S}}^{(w)}(S,t)=\operatorname{e}^{-\frac{1}{2}(k+1)x-\frac{1}{4}(k+1)^{2}\tau+k\tau }\tilde{\tilde{H}}(\tau,x)\), and \(\tilde {\tilde{H}}_{2}\) satisfies the nonhomogeneous heat equation
with zero initial condition. Hence,
From the boundedness of Sf S (S,t) it follows that \(\tilde{\tilde{H}}_{2}(\tau ,x)=O(\operatorname{e}^{\frac{1}{2}(k-1)x})\), and we conclude that \(SH_{2_{S}}^{(w)}(S,t)\) is bounded on \(\mathbb{R}_{++}\times { [0,T]}\). Using Remark 6.1, it follows that \(S^{2}Y^{(w)} H_{2_{S}}^{(w)}\) is bounded there, too. Then \(H_{3}{^{(w)^{\pm}}}(S,t)=\mp M^{(w)}(T-t)\mp M_{1}^{(w)}\), as defined in (6.5), will satisfy (6.18) with M (w) big enough and \(M_{1}^{(w)}\) as defined in (6.6). In either case, \(SH_{3_{S}}^{{ (j)^{+}}}(S,t)\equiv 0\), j=1,w. □
Proof of Lemma 3.11
From Assumptions 3.8 and 3.9, all the bounds in Lemma 4.1 hold on \(\mathbb{D}\). The reader can now verify that on \(\mathbf{NT}^{\mathbf{{ (b)}}}\) the conclusion of Theorem 5.5 holds, too. Note that this proof is a replication of the original proof as all the necessary boundedness conditions in Lemma 4.1 are satisfied, and the assertion needs to be proved on a deterministic domain \(\mathbf{NT}^{\mathbf{{ (b)}}}\). To complete the proof, we have to show what happens on the boundary {S=b} of the \(\mathbf{NT}^{\mathbf{{ (b)}}}\) region. We show that on this boundary, \(\psi^{{ { (b)}^{+}}} \ge \psi^{{(1)^{+}}}\) and \(\psi^{{ { (b)}^{-}}} \le\psi^{{(1)^{-}}}\), therefore allowing us to complete the proof by continuing the trading in \(\mathbf{NT^{(1)}}\) if necessary. This defines \(Q^{{ { (b)}^{\pm}}}\), and without loss of generality, we may assume that the constant \(M_{1}^{{ (b)}}\) in the definition of \(H_{3}^{{ { (b)}^{\pm}}}\) in (6.5) satisfies
and M (b) is big enough. We also define \(\psi^{{ { (b)}^{\pm}}}\) by setting j=b in (5.5). It then follows that if τ<T, using \(P_{b}(b,\tau)=H_{2}^{{ (b)}}(b,\tau)=0\) for ε>0 small enough, we get
We can now prove the equivalent of Theorem 3.6. Hence, on [0,τ] the proof of Theorem 3.6 holds. Namely, we have for \((t,B,y,S)\in { [0,T]}\times \mathbb{R}\times \mathbb{R}\times[0,b )\) that
where we have used that \((\psi^{{ { (b)}^{+}}}(t\wedge\tau,B_{t\wedge\tau}, y_{t\wedge\tau}, S_{t\wedge\tau}))\) is a supermartingale to obtain the first inequality, (A.2) to establish the second, and Theorem 3.6 with j=1 for the last inequality. Maximizing over all admissible strategies, we conclude that
Similarly,
As a corollary, we conclude that Lemma 3.11 holds. □
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Bichuch, M. Pricing a contingent claim liability with transaction costs using asymptotic analysis for optimal investment. Finance Stoch 18, 651–694 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-014-0233-z
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00780-014-0233-z