Abstract
Nowadays, along with increased public demands on the high-quality green fresh product, the downstream retailer has to spend in the packaging and cold chain transportation and the upstream farmer needs to invest more in green fresh products producing. In this paper, we investigate a green fresh product supply chain problem, in which the retailer transports and sells green fresh products to the ultimate consumer while the farmer produces green fresh product through spending a greenness improvement investment and sells green fresh products to the retailer. Since the fresh product is perishable, the retailer needs to make a costly freshness-keeping effort. Obviously, the freshness-keeping effort, the price, and the greenness improvement level will affect the demand. Thus, to demonstrate the game structure between the retailer and the farmer, a decentralized model without cost sharing, a decentralized Stackelberg cost sharing model, and a Nash bargaining model with cost sharing are formulated. Results show that: (1) The equilibrium decisions under Stackelberg model with cost sharing are larger than that of the Nash bargaining model with cost sharing, while equilibrium decisions in the decentralized model without cost sharing are the least. (2) Both greenness improvement levels in Stackelberg cost sharing contract and Nash bargaining are greater than that in decentralized model without cost sharing. (3) The retailer’s profits in Stackelberg cost sharing contract and Nash bargaining are larger than that in decentralized case without cost sharing, while the farmer’s profits in Stackelberg cost sharing contract and Nash bargaining are larger than in decentralized model without cost sharing in certain conditions. Meanwhile, a numerical example is given to illustrate the results we obtained in the theoretical analysis process.
Similar content being viewed by others
Explore related subjects
Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.References
Bolton J, Liu W (2006) Creating an effective China cold supply chain—current status, challenges and implementation considerations. Accenture Report. http://www.procurementleaders.com/8201/23171/. Accessed 5 Mar 2013
Cachon G (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. Handb Oper Res Manag Sci 11:227–339
Cai X, Zhou X (2014) Optimal policies for perishable products when transportation to export market is disrupted. Prod Oper Manag 23(5):907–923
Cai X, Chen J, Xiao Y, Xu X (2010) Optimization and coordination of fresh product supply chains with freshness-keeping effort. Prod Oper Manag 19(3):261–278
Chao X, Gong X, Shi C, Zhang H (2015) Approximation algorithms for perishable inventory systems. Oper Res 63(3):585–601
Chen C (2001) Design for the environment: a quality-based model for green product development. Manag Sci 47(2):250–263
Chen J, Cao Q (2018) Decision of fresh-keeping investment in agricultural supply chains under different settlement mode. J Syst Eng 33(3):378–386
Chen Y, Liu Y (2018) A new equilibrium optimization method for hybrid uncertain decision-making system. J Uncertain Syst 12(3):224–240
Chen X, Zhang H, Zhang M et al (2017) Optimal decisions in a retailer Stackelberg supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 187:260–270
Chen J, Dong M, Xu L (2018a) A perishable product shipment consolidation model considering freshness-keeping effort. Transp Res E-Log 115(2018):56–86
Chen Z, Lan Y, Zhao R (2018b) Impacts of risk attitude and outside option on compensation contracts under different information structures. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak 17:13–47
ChinaIRN.Com (2017) Analyzing the 100 billion loss suffered by China in cold chain. http://www.chinairn.com/news/20130305/100408745.html. Accessed 5 Mar 2013
Chintapalli P, Hazra J (2016) Stocking and quality decisions for deteriorating perishable products under competition. J Oper Res Soc 67(4):593–603
Dangelico R, Pontrandolfo P (2015) Being green and competitive: the impact of environmental actions and collaborations on firm performance. Bus Strat Environ 24:413–430
Dey K, Saha S (2018) Influence of procurement decisions in two-period green supply chain. J Clean Prod 190:388–402
Doris S (1998) Keeping freshness in fresh-cut product. Agric Res 46(2):12–14
Ghosh D, Shah J (2015) Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract. Int J Prod Econ 164:319–329
Hong Z, Guo X (2019) Green product supply chain contracts considering environmental responsibilities. Omega Int J Manag Sci 83:155–166
Hou X, Liu D (2017) Building fresh product supply chain cooperation in a typical wholesale market. J Oper Res Soc 68(5):566–576
Li Q, Xiao T, Qiu Y (2018) Price and carbon emission reduction decisions and revenue-sharing contract considering fairness concerns. J Clean Prod 190:303–314
Liu Z, Anderson T, Cruz J (2012) Consumer environmental awareness and competition in two-stage supply chains. Eur J Oper Res 218(3):602–613
Liu H, Zhang J, Zhou C, Ru Y (2018) Optimal purchase and inventory retrieval policies for perishable seasonal agricultural products. Omega Int J Manag Sci 79:133–145
Plambeck EL, Denend L (2011) The greening of Wal-Mart’s supply chain revisited. Supply Chain Manag Rev 15(5):16–23
Song H, Gao X (2018) Green supply chain game model and analysis under revenue-sharing contract. J Clean Prod 170:183–192
Thomson G (2017) Food date labels and hunger in America. Concordia Law Rev 2(1):143–166
Wang C, Chen X (2018) Joint order and pricing decisions for fresh produce with put option contracts. J Oper Res Soc 69(3):474–484
Wang G, Tang W, Zhao R (2013) An uncertain price discrimination model in labor market. Soft Comput 17(4):579–585
Wu Q, Mu Y, Feng Y (2015) Coordinating contracts for fresh product outsourcing logistics channels with power structures. Int J Prod Econ 160:94–105
Xiao Y, Chen J (2012) Supply chain management of fresh products with producer transportation. Decis Sci 43:785–815
Yan Y, Zhao R, Chen H (2018a) Prisoner’s dilemma on competing retailers’ investment in green supply chain management. J Clean Prod 184:65–81
Yan Y, Zhao R, Xing T (2018b) Strategic introduction of the marketplace channel under dual upstream disadvantages in sales efficiency and demand information. Eur J Oper Res 273:968–982
Yang D, Xiao T (2017) Pricing and green level decisions of a green supply chain with governmental interventions under fuzzy uncertainties. J Clean Prod 149:1174–1187
Yang K, Lan Y, Zhao R (2017) Monitoring mechanisms in new product development with risk-averse project manager. J Intell Manuf 28(3):667–681
Yu Y, Xiao T (2017) Pricing and cold-chain service level decisions in a fresh agri-products supply chain with logistics outsourcing. Comput Ind Eng 111:56–66
Zhang H et al (2018) Risk assessment model of agricultural products cold chain logistics based on the improved catastrophe progression method. J Syst Eng 33(3):412–421
Zheng Q, Ieromonachou P, Fan T, Zhou L (2017) Supply chain contracting coordination for fresh products with fresh-keeping effort. Ind Manag Data Syst 117(3):538–559
Acknowledgements
This work was supported by Philosophy and Social Science Foundation of Tianjin (No. TJGL16-009Q).
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding authors
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Human and animal rights
This study does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.
Additional information
Communicated by Y. Ni.
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix
Appendix
1.1 Appendix A: Summary of abbreviations
1.2 Appendix B: Model solving process and proofs of Propositions
The centralized channel case. The whole channel supply chain profit function can be rewritten as
The first-order condition
and
The second-order condition
and
Moreover, we can also obtain
Thus, the Hessian matrix is
Through computing the Hessian Matrix, when the conditions \(2bL-\beta ^2>0\) and \(-2\,bLK+{\beta }^{2}K+{\alpha }^{2}L<0\) are satisfied, the supply chain profit function is joint concave with respect to the decision variables. Thus, equating the first-order condition to 0 and solving the equations, we obtain
and
Subsequently, the optimal profit of the centralized supply chain is
Proof of Proposition1
Proof
We can easily get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)
Proof of Corollary 1
Proof
According to the analytical expressions given above, we can easily get the results by implementing differentiation. \(\square \)
The decentralized channel case. Under this environment, we solve the farmer’s optimization problem first:
Rewriting as
The Hessian matrix is
Through computing the Hessian matrix, the farmer’s profit function is joint concave with respect to the decision variables when \(2bK-\alpha ^2>0\). The first-order condition is
and
Thus, equating the first-order condition to 0 and solving the equations, we get
and
We substitute Eqs. (21)–(22) into the retailer’s profit function (1) and derive
By computing the first-order condition
and the second-order condition
we can write the Hessian matrix of \(\pi _\mathrm{R}\) as
Through computing the Hessian matrix, the retailer’s profit function is joint concave with respect to the decision variables when \(\frac{b^2K(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}{(2Kb-\alpha ^2)^2}>0\), i.e., \(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2>0\). Let the first-order condition be 0. We get
and
Then, we have
Proof of Proposition2
Proof
We can easily get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 3
Proof
The above relationships can be proved easily through algebraic comparison. \(\square \)
The model with cost sharing. Due to the game structure, we solve for the farmer’s profit function first:
The first-order condition
and the second-order condition
We can write the Hessian matrix as
Since
then the Hessian matrix is negative definite if
Thus, the farmer’s profit function is jointly concave in w and \(\theta \). Let the first condition be zero, we obtain
Substituting Eqs. (24–25) into (5), we can derive
According to the first-order condition
and the second-order condition
Then, the Hessian matrix is negative definite if
and
Equivalent to
and
which implies
and
By the first-order condition, we have
Substituting m and \(\zeta \) into Eq. (26), we can obtain the retailer’s profit function with respect to \(\psi \)
Then, the first-order condition
and the second-order condition
The second-order condition is negative if \(A_9>0.\) Thus, \(\pi _\mathrm{R}(\psi )\) is concave in \(\psi \) for the above condition. Solving the first-order condition for \(\psi \) gives \(\psi =\frac{1}{3}\) or \(\psi =1\).
When \(\psi =1\), \(A_9>0\) can be reduced to \(-L\alpha ^2>0\), which is a contradiction since \(L,K, \alpha ,\beta >0\).
Logically, the equilibrium \(\psi ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}=\frac{1}{3}\). Substituting the value of \(\psi ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}=\frac{1}{3}\) into the expressions accordingly, we get
Proof of Proposition4
Proof
We can easily get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)
Proof of Corollary 2
Proof
During the computation process, the
By computing the first-order derivative, we can obtain the result. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 5
Proof
We prove the result about \(\zeta \); the result about w can be proved analogously. During the computation process, the
By computing the first-order derivative with respect to \(\psi \) and making analysis, we can obtain the result. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 6
Proof
By computing the first-order derivative with respect to \(\psi \) and making analysis, we can obtain the result. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 7
Proof
The result can be proved analogously with Proposition 5. \(\square \)
Bargaining cost sharing contract model. Since the farmer and the retailer decide the \(\psi \) via bargaining, we formulate the objective function as
Due to the game structure, we solve the farmer’s optimization problem first:
The first-order condition
and the second-order condition
We can write the Hessian matrix as
The Hessian matrix is negative definite if
Under this assumption, the farmer’s profit function is joint concave in p and \(\zeta \). Let the first-order condition be zero and solve equations for p and \(\zeta \). We can obtain
and
Substituting Eqs. (29–30) into the retailer’s profit function, we get
The first-order condition
and the second-order condition
Then, the Hessian matrix is negative definite if
and
Equivalent to
and
which implies
and
Let the first-order condition be zero and solve equations for m and \(\zeta \). We can get
Substituting m and \(\zeta \) into Eqs. (29–30) and the Nash bargaining function (27). By computing the first-order condition and the second-order condition of the bargaining model
The first-order condition
The second-order condition
The second-order condition is negative if \(A_2<0.\) Thus, the objective function is concave in \(\psi \) for the above condition. Let the first-order condition be 0. We obtain \(\psi =1\),
or
When \(\psi =1\), \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2>0\) can be deduced to \(-\alpha ^2>0\), which is a contradiction. Meanwhile, if
then the \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2>0\) is not satisfied. When
If \(12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2<0\), then we can get \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2<0\); if \(12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2>0\), we only need to check \((12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2)^2-(2bA_3)^2\) is greater than or less than 0. By algebra,
The problem transfers to verify whether \(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2\) is greater or less than 0. Since we have \(2KLb-\beta ^2K-L\alpha ^2>0\) and \(2Kb-\alpha ^2>0\), \(2b(2KLb-\beta ^2K-L\alpha ^2)>0\) and \(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-2\beta ^2Kb>0\). Owing to \(2Kb-\alpha ^2>0\), we can derive \(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2>0\). Thus, \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2<0\) when
Obviously, the
should be omitted. Analogously, we can also prove that \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2>0\) can be satisfied when
Thus, the equilibrium
The equilibrium decisions and profit functions are
Proof of Proposition 8
Proof
We can get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)
Model comparison.
Proof of Proposition 9
Proof
We need to prove \(10KLb+2K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2-3A_3<0\) which is equivalent to \((10KLb+2K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2)^2-(3A_3)^2<0\). By algebra, we need to prove
which is true since \(K>0\) and \(16KLb-4K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2>0\). \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 10
Proof
We prove \(w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}\) for example. The proofs of \(\theta ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>\theta ^{\mathrm{D}^{*}},\,p^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>p^{\mathrm{D}^{*}},\zeta ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>\zeta ^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}\) can be done analogously.
The \(w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}=\frac{12KLbc-4K\beta ^2c-9L\alpha ^2c+4KLa}{16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2}\) and the \(w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{[L(3bc+a)-c\beta ^2]K-2Lc\alpha ^2}{4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2}\). It is equivalent to prove \(\frac{w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}}{w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}}>1\).
Obviously, \(a-bc>0\) holds true. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 11
Proof
The proof can be obtained with the first-order derivative. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 12
Proof
The proof of (1) can be derived from Propositions 7 and 9; the proof of (2) is analogous to Proposition 10. \(\square \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Wang, G., Ding, P., Chen, H. et al. Green fresh product cost sharing contracts considering freshness-keeping effort. Soft Comput 24, 2671–2691 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-019-03828-4
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-019-03828-4