[go: up one dir, main page]
More Web Proxy on the site http://driver.im/ Skip to main content
Log in

Green fresh product cost sharing contracts considering freshness-keeping effort

  • Focus
  • Published:
Soft Computing Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Nowadays, along with increased public demands on the high-quality green fresh product, the downstream retailer has to spend in the packaging and cold chain transportation and the upstream farmer needs to invest more in green fresh products producing. In this paper, we investigate a green fresh product supply chain problem, in which the retailer transports and sells green fresh products to the ultimate consumer while the farmer produces green fresh product through spending a greenness improvement investment and sells green fresh products to the retailer. Since the fresh product is perishable, the retailer needs to make a costly freshness-keeping effort. Obviously, the freshness-keeping effort, the price, and the greenness improvement level will affect the demand. Thus, to demonstrate the game structure between the retailer and the farmer, a decentralized model without cost sharing, a decentralized Stackelberg cost sharing model, and a Nash bargaining model with cost sharing are formulated. Results show that: (1) The equilibrium decisions under Stackelberg model with cost sharing are larger than that of the Nash bargaining model with cost sharing, while equilibrium decisions in the decentralized model without cost sharing are the least. (2) Both greenness improvement levels in Stackelberg cost sharing contract and Nash bargaining are greater than that in decentralized model without cost sharing. (3) The retailer’s profits in Stackelberg cost sharing contract and Nash bargaining are larger than that in decentralized case without cost sharing, while the farmer’s profits in Stackelberg cost sharing contract and Nash bargaining are larger than in decentralized model without cost sharing in certain conditions. Meanwhile, a numerical example is given to illustrate the results we obtained in the theoretical analysis process.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
£29.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price includes VAT (United Kingdom)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Explore related subjects

Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.

Notes

  1. http://zfs.mee.gov.cn/fl/201809/t20180907_549845.shtml.

References

  • Bolton J, Liu W (2006) Creating an effective China cold supply chain—current status, challenges and implementation considerations. Accenture Report. http://www.procurementleaders.com/8201/23171/. Accessed 5 Mar 2013

  • Cachon G (2003) Supply chain coordination with contracts. Handb Oper Res Manag Sci 11:227–339

    Google Scholar 

  • Cai X, Zhou X (2014) Optimal policies for perishable products when transportation to export market is disrupted. Prod Oper Manag 23(5):907–923

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai X, Chen J, Xiao Y, Xu X (2010) Optimization and coordination of fresh product supply chains with freshness-keeping effort. Prod Oper Manag 19(3):261–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao X, Gong X, Shi C, Zhang H (2015) Approximation algorithms for perishable inventory systems. Oper Res 63(3):585–601

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chen C (2001) Design for the environment: a quality-based model for green product development. Manag Sci 47(2):250–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen J, Cao Q (2018) Decision of fresh-keeping investment in agricultural supply chains under different settlement mode. J Syst Eng 33(3):378–386

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y, Liu Y (2018) A new equilibrium optimization method for hybrid uncertain decision-making system. J Uncertain Syst 12(3):224–240

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen X, Zhang H, Zhang M et al (2017) Optimal decisions in a retailer Stackelberg supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 187:260–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen J, Dong M, Xu L (2018a) A perishable product shipment consolidation model considering freshness-keeping effort. Transp Res E-Log 115(2018):56–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Lan Y, Zhao R (2018b) Impacts of risk attitude and outside option on compensation contracts under different information structures. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak 17:13–47

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • ChinaIRN.Com (2017) Analyzing the 100 billion loss suffered by China in cold chain. http://www.chinairn.com/news/20130305/100408745.html. Accessed 5 Mar 2013

  • Chintapalli P, Hazra J (2016) Stocking and quality decisions for deteriorating perishable products under competition. J Oper Res Soc 67(4):593–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dangelico R, Pontrandolfo P (2015) Being green and competitive: the impact of environmental actions and collaborations on firm performance. Bus Strat Environ 24:413–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dey K, Saha S (2018) Influence of procurement decisions in two-period green supply chain. J Clean Prod 190:388–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doris S (1998) Keeping freshness in fresh-cut product. Agric Res 46(2):12–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh D, Shah J (2015) Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract. Int J Prod Econ 164:319–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong Z, Guo X (2019) Green product supply chain contracts considering environmental responsibilities. Omega Int J Manag Sci 83:155–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou X, Liu D (2017) Building fresh product supply chain cooperation in a typical wholesale market. J Oper Res Soc 68(5):566–576

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Li Q, Xiao T, Qiu Y (2018) Price and carbon emission reduction decisions and revenue-sharing contract considering fairness concerns. J Clean Prod 190:303–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Z, Anderson T, Cruz J (2012) Consumer environmental awareness and competition in two-stage supply chains. Eur J Oper Res 218(3):602–613

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Liu H, Zhang J, Zhou C, Ru Y (2018) Optimal purchase and inventory retrieval policies for perishable seasonal agricultural products. Omega Int J Manag Sci 79:133–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck EL, Denend L (2011) The greening of Wal-Mart’s supply chain revisited. Supply Chain Manag Rev 15(5):16–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Song H, Gao X (2018) Green supply chain game model and analysis under revenue-sharing contract. J Clean Prod 170:183–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson G (2017) Food date labels and hunger in America. Concordia Law Rev 2(1):143–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang C, Chen X (2018) Joint order and pricing decisions for fresh produce with put option contracts. J Oper Res Soc 69(3):474–484

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Wang G, Tang W, Zhao R (2013) An uncertain price discrimination model in labor market. Soft Comput 17(4):579–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu Q, Mu Y, Feng Y (2015) Coordinating contracts for fresh product outsourcing logistics channels with power structures. Int J Prod Econ 160:94–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiao Y, Chen J (2012) Supply chain management of fresh products with producer transportation. Decis Sci 43:785–815

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yan Y, Zhao R, Chen H (2018a) Prisoner’s dilemma on competing retailers’ investment in green supply chain management. J Clean Prod 184:65–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yan Y, Zhao R, Xing T (2018b) Strategic introduction of the marketplace channel under dual upstream disadvantages in sales efficiency and demand information. Eur J Oper Res 273:968–982

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Yang D, Xiao T (2017) Pricing and green level decisions of a green supply chain with governmental interventions under fuzzy uncertainties. J Clean Prod 149:1174–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang K, Lan Y, Zhao R (2017) Monitoring mechanisms in new product development with risk-averse project manager. J Intell Manuf 28(3):667–681

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu Y, Xiao T (2017) Pricing and cold-chain service level decisions in a fresh agri-products supply chain with logistics outsourcing. Comput Ind Eng 111:56–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang H et al (2018) Risk assessment model of agricultural products cold chain logistics based on the improved catastrophe progression method. J Syst Eng 33(3):412–421

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng Q, Ieromonachou P, Fan T, Zhou L (2017) Supply chain contracting coordination for fresh products with fresh-keeping effort. Ind Manag Data Syst 117(3):538–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by Philosophy and Social Science Foundation of Tianjin (No. TJGL16-009Q).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Peiqi Ding or Huiru Chen.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Human and animal rights

This study does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Additional information

Communicated by Y. Ni.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Appendix A: Summary of abbreviations

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} {\hat{\psi }}&=\frac{2KLb+K\beta ^2-\sqrt{K^2L^2b^2-2K^2Lb\beta ^2+K^2\beta ^4+KL^2\alpha ^2b+2KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2}}{K(Lb+2\beta ^2)}\\ A_1&=14KLb\psi ^2+K\beta ^2\psi ^2-16KLb\psi -2K\beta ^2\psi \\&\quad +6L\alpha ^2\psi +2KLb+K\beta ^2-L\alpha ^2\\ A_2&=56K^2L^2b^2\psi ^4-10K^2Lb\beta ^2\psi ^4-K^2\beta ^4\psi ^4-152K^2L^2b^2\psi ^3\\&\quad +22K^2Lb\beta ^2\psi ^3\\&\quad +4K^2\beta ^4\psi ^3- 6KL^2\alpha ^2b\psi ^3-12KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2\psi ^3\\&\quad +120K^2L^2b^2\psi ^2-6K^2Lb\beta ^2\psi ^2\\&\quad - 6K^2\beta ^4 \psi ^2-2KL^2\alpha ^2b\psi ^2+23KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2\psi ^2-9L^2\alpha ^4\psi ^2\\&\quad - 8K^2L^2b^2\psi -14K^2Lb\beta ^2\psi +4K^2\beta ^4\psi -8KL^2\alpha ^2b\psi \\&\quad -10KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2\psi +3L^2\alpha ^4\psi -16K^2L^2b^2\\&\quad +8K^2Lb\beta ^2-K^2\beta ^4+ 16KL^2\alpha ^2b-KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2-4L^2\alpha ^4.\\ A_3&=\sqrt{36K^2L^2b^2-34KL^2\alpha ^2b-5KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2+9L^2\alpha ^4}.\\ A_4&=(-2Kb^2c{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2+2bKa{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2+4Kb^2c\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\\&\quad -2\alpha ^2bc\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-4bKa\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\\&\quad -2Kb^2c+2a\alpha ^2\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}+\alpha ^2bc+2bKa-a\alpha ^2)L\\ A_5&=6KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-12KLb\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}+2K\beta ^2\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\\&\quad +4L\alpha ^2\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}} +6KLb-K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2\\ A_6&=\sqrt{64K^2L^2b^2-48KL^2\alpha ^2b-12KL\alpha ^2\beta ^2+9L^2\alpha ^4}\\ A_7&=16\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3-{K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3-8\,K{ L}^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3\\&\quad -32\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-4\,{ K}^{2}Lb{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2\\&\quad +3\,{K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2+24\,K{L} ^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2+2\,KL{\alpha }^{2}{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-4\, {L}^{2}{\alpha }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2\\&\quad +16\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\\&\quad + 8\,{K}^{2} Lb{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}-3\,{K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}{\psi ^{ \mathrm {B}^{*}}}-14\,K{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b {\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}-4\,KL{\alpha }^{2}{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}\\&\quad +3 \,{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}\\&\quad -4\,{K }^{2}Lb{\beta }^{2}+{K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}+2\,KL{\alpha }^{2}{\beta }^{2}\\ A_8&=64\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3+16\,{K}^{2}Lb{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3 -8\,{K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3\\&\quad -54\,K{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^3- 64\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2\\&\quad -80\,{K}^{2}Lb{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2 +24\,{K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2\\&\quad +102\,K{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2 +24\,KL{\alpha }^{2}{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2\\&\quad -27\,{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2\\&\quad -64\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+112\,{K}^{2}Lb{\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}-24\,{ K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}\\&\quad +30\,K{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}-48\,KL{\alpha }^{2} {\beta }^{2}{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}\\&\quad +64\,{K}^{2}{L}^{2}{b}^{2}-48\,{K}^{2}Lb{\beta }^{2}+8\, {K}^{2}{\beta }^{4}-62\,K{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{2}b\\&\quad +24\,KL{\alpha }^{2}{\beta } ^{2}+15\,{L}^{2}{\alpha }^{4}\\ A_9&=12KLb\psi ^3-3K\beta ^2\psi ^3-24KLb\psi ^2+6K\beta ^2\psi ^2\\&\quad +12KLb\psi -3K\beta ^2\psi -L\alpha ^2\\&\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}=\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2-A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}\\ {\underline{K}}&=\frac{(31Lb-12\beta ^2-\sqrt{L^2b^2-24Lb\beta ^2 +24\beta ^4})\alpha ^2L}{8(8L^2b^2-6Lb\beta ^2+\beta ^4)}\\ {\overline{K}}&=\frac{(31Lb-12\beta ^2+\sqrt{L^2b^2-24Lb\beta ^2 +24\beta ^4})\alpha ^2L}{8(8L^2b^2-6Lb\beta ^2+\beta ^4)} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Appendix B: Model solving process and proofs of Propositions

The centralized channel case. The whole channel supply chain profit function can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{p,\zeta ,\theta } \pi _\mathrm{SC}=(p-c)(a-bp+\alpha \theta +\beta \zeta )-\frac{1}{2}L\zeta ^2-\frac{1}{2}K\theta ^2. \end{aligned}$$
(9)

The first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial p}=\beta \zeta +\alpha \theta -bp+a-(p-c)b, \end{aligned}$$
(10)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial \zeta }=p \beta -c \beta -L \zeta \end{aligned}$$
(11)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial \theta }=p \alpha -c \alpha -K \theta . \end{aligned}$$
(12)

The second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial p^2}=-2b, \end{aligned}$$
(13)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial \zeta ^2}=-L \end{aligned}$$
(14)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial \theta ^2}=-K. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

Moreover, we can also obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial p\partial \zeta }=\beta ,\quad \frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial p\partial \theta }=\alpha ,\quad \frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{SC}}{ \partial \zeta \partial \theta }=0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the Hessian matrix is

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{ccc} -2b &{}\beta &{}\alpha \\ \beta &{} -L&{}0 \\ \alpha &{}0&{}-K\\ \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Through computing the Hessian Matrix, when the conditions \(2bL-\beta ^2>0\) and \(-2\,bLK+{\beta }^{2}K+{\alpha }^{2}L<0\) are satisfied, the supply chain profit function is joint concave with respect to the decision variables. Thus, equating the first-order condition to 0 and solving the equations, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned}&p^{*}={\frac{KLbc-K{\beta }^{2}c-L{\alpha }^{2}c+KLa}{2\,bLK-{\beta }^{2}K-{ \alpha }^{2}L}}, \end{aligned}$$
(17)
$$\begin{aligned}&\zeta ^{*}={\frac{K\beta \, \left( -bc+a \right) }{2\,bLK-{\beta }^{2}K-{\alpha }^{ 2}L}}, \end{aligned}$$
(18)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \theta ^{*}={\frac{L\alpha \, \left( -bc+a \right) }{2\,bLK-{\beta }^{2}K-{\alpha }^ {2}L}} . \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Subsequently, the optimal profit of the centralized supply chain is

$$\begin{aligned} \pi ^*_\mathrm{sc}=\frac{KL \left( -bc+a \right) ^{2}}{2(2\,bLK-{\beta }^{2}K-{ \alpha }^{2}L)}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition1

Proof

We can easily get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 1

Proof

According to the analytical expressions given above, we can easily get the results by implementing differentiation. \(\square \)

The decentralized channel case. Under this environment, we solve the farmer’s optimization problem first:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{w,\theta } \pi _\mathrm{F}=(w-c)q-\frac{1}{2}K\theta ^2 . \end{aligned}$$

Rewriting as

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{w,\theta } \pi _\mathrm{F}=(w-c)[a-b(w+m)+\alpha \theta +\beta \zeta ]-\frac{1}{2}K\theta ^2 . \end{aligned}$$

The Hessian matrix is

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{cc} -2b &{}\alpha \\ \alpha &{}-K\\ \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Through computing the Hessian matrix, the farmer’s profit function is joint concave with respect to the decision variables when \(2bK-\alpha ^2>0\). The first-order condition is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w}=a-b \left( w+m \right) +\alpha \,\theta +\beta \zeta - \left( w-c \right) b \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial \theta }=(w-c)\alpha -K \theta . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, equating the first-order condition to 0 and solving the equations, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \theta (m,\zeta )={\frac{\alpha \, \left( \beta \zeta -bc-bm+a \right) }{2\,Kb-{\alpha }^{2}}} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

and

$$\begin{aligned} w(m,\zeta )={\frac{K\zeta \beta +Kbc-Kbm-{\alpha }^{2}c+Ka}{2\,Kb -{\alpha }^{2}}}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

We substitute Eqs. (21)–(22) into the retailer’s profit function (1) and derive

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{m,\zeta }\pi _\mathrm{R}=\frac{L\zeta ^2\alpha ^2-2bk[mb(c+m)-m(\beta \zeta +a)+L \zeta ^2]}{4Kb-2\alpha ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

By computing the first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m}=\frac{bK[a+\beta \zeta -bc-2mb]}{2Kb-\alpha ^2}, \\&\frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial \zeta }=\frac{L\zeta \alpha ^2+bk(\beta m-2L\zeta )}{2Kb-\alpha ^2}, \end{aligned}$$

and the second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m^2}=\frac{-2Kb^2}{2Kb-\alpha ^2}, \\&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial \zeta ^2}=\frac{L\alpha ^2-2LbK}{2Kb-\alpha ^2}, \\&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m \partial \zeta }=\frac{\beta bK}{2Kb-\alpha ^2}, \end{aligned}$$

we can write the Hessian matrix of \(\pi _\mathrm{R}\) as

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{cc} \frac{-2Kb^2}{2Kb-\alpha ^2} &{}\frac{\beta bK}{2Kb-\alpha ^2} \\ \frac{\beta bK}{2Kb-\alpha ^2} &{} \frac{L\alpha ^2-2LbK}{2Kb-\alpha ^2} \\ \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Through computing the Hessian matrix, the retailer’s profit function is joint concave with respect to the decision variables when \(\frac{b^2K(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}{(2Kb-\alpha ^2)^2}>0\), i.e., \(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2>0\). Let the first-order condition be 0. We get

$$\begin{aligned} \zeta ^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{\beta K(a-bc)}{4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} m^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{L(\alpha ^2 bc+2Kab-a\alpha ^2-2Kb^2c)}{b(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, we have

$$\begin{aligned}&\theta ^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{L\alpha (a-bc)}{4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2}, \\&w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{[L(3bc+a)-c\beta ^2]K-2Lc\alpha ^2}{4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2}, \\&p^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}+m^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{KLb^2c-Kb\beta ^2c-L\alpha ^2bc+3KLab-La\alpha ^2}{b(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}, \\&\pi _\mathrm{R}^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{KL(a-bc)^2}{2(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}, \\&\pi _\mathrm{F}^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{KL^2(a-bc)^2(2Kb-\alpha ^2)}{2(4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)^2}, \\&\pi _\mathrm{SC}^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{KL(-bc+a)^2(6KLb-K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2)}{2(4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition2

Proof

We can easily get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

Proof

The above relationships can be proved easily through algebraic comparison. \(\square \)

The model with cost sharing. Due to the game structure, we solve for the farmer’s profit function first:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{w,\theta }\pi _\mathrm{F}=(w-c)q-\frac{1}{2}K(1-\psi )\theta ^2. \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w}=a+\alpha \theta +\beta \zeta +cb-2bw-bm,\\&\frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial \theta }=(w-c)\alpha -K(1-\psi ) \theta , \end{aligned}$$

and the second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w^2}=-2b,\\&\frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial \theta ^2}=-K(1-\psi ) ,\\&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w\partial \theta }=\alpha . \end{aligned}$$

We can write the Hessian matrix as

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{cc} -2b &{}\alpha \\ \alpha &{} -K(1-\psi ) \\ \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Since

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w^2}=-2b<0, \end{aligned}$$

then the Hessian matrix is negative definite if

$$\begin{aligned} K(1-\psi )\cdot 2b -\alpha \cdot \alpha >0. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the farmer’s profit function is jointly concave in w and \(\theta \). Let the first condition be zero, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned}&\theta (\zeta ,m)=-{\frac{\alpha \, \left( \beta \zeta -bc-bm+a \right) }{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}, \end{aligned}$$
(24)
$$\begin{aligned}&w(\zeta ,m)=\frac{K(1-\psi )(bm-bc-\beta \zeta -a)+\alpha ^2c}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Substituting Eqs. (2425) into (5), we can derive

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\max _{m,\zeta }\pi _\mathrm{R}\\&\quad = m\left( a-b \left( {\frac{ ( ( c-m ) b+\beta \zeta +a)( \psi -1) K+{\alpha }^{2} c}{2\,Kb\psi -2Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}+m \right) \right. \\&\qquad \left. -\,{\frac{{\alpha }^{2} ( \beta \zeta -bc-bm+a) }{2\,Kb\psi -2\,K b+{\alpha }^{2}}}+\beta \zeta \right) \\&\qquad -\,\frac{1}{2}L{\zeta }^ {2}-\frac{1}{2}{\frac{K{\alpha }^{2} ( \beta \zeta -bc -bm+a ) ^{2}\psi }{ ( 2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}) ^ {2}}}. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(26)

According to the first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m}&=a-b \left( {\frac{ \left( \left( c-m \right) b+\beta \, \left( \zeta \right) +a \right) \left( \psi -1 \right) K+{\alpha }^{2}c}{2\,Kb\psi - 2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}+m \right) \\&\quad -{\frac{{\alpha }^{2} \left( \beta \, \left( \zeta \right) -bc-bm+a \right) }{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}} }+\beta \zeta \\&\quad +m \left( -b \left( -{\frac{b \left( \psi -1 \right) K}{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}+1 \right) \right. \\&\quad +\left. {\frac{{ \alpha }^{2}b}{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}} \right) \\&\quad +{\frac{K{\alpha }^{2} \left( \beta \, \left( \zeta \right) -bc-bm+a \right) \psi \,b}{ \left( 2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2} \right) ^{2}}},\\ \frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial \zeta }&= m\left( -\frac{b\beta (\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\right. \\&\left. \quad -\frac{\alpha ^2\beta }{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+\beta \right) \\&\quad -L\zeta -\frac{K\alpha ^2(\beta \zeta -bc-bm+a)\psi \beta }{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

and the second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m^2}= & {} -2b\left( -\frac{b(\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+1\right) \\&+\frac{2 \alpha ^2b}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\\&-\frac{K\alpha ^2b^2\psi }{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2},\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial \zeta ^2}= & {} -L-{\frac{K{\alpha }^{2}\beta ^2\psi }{ \left( 2\,Kb\psi +{\alpha }^{2}-2\,Kb \right) ^{2}}},\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{\partial m\partial \zeta }= & {} -\frac{b\beta (\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\!-\! \frac{\alpha ^2\beta }{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+\beta \\&+\frac{K\alpha ^2\beta \psi b}{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, the Hessian matrix is negative definite if

$$\begin{aligned}&-2b\left( -\frac{b(\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+1\right) +\frac{2\alpha ^2b}{2Kb \psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\\&\quad -\frac{K\alpha ^2b^2\psi }{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}<0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{b^2K(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{b^2K(4Kb\psi ^2-8Kb\psi +3\alpha ^2\psi +4Kb-2\alpha ^2)}{(2Kb \psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}<0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned}&4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi \\&\quad +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2>0, \end{aligned}$$

which implies

$$\begin{aligned} 4Kb\psi ^2-8Kb\psi +3\alpha ^2\psi +4Kb-2\alpha ^2>0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} L(4Kb\psi ^2-8Kb\psi +3\alpha ^2\psi +4Kb-2\alpha ^2)-K\beta ^2(\psi -1)^2>0. \end{aligned}$$

By the first-order condition, we have

$$\begin{aligned}&m=\frac{A_4}{b(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)}, \\&\zeta =\frac{K\beta (-bc\psi ^2+a\psi ^2+2bc\psi -2a\psi -bc+a)}{4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2\psi +4KLb-K \beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting m and \(\zeta \) into Eq. (26), we can obtain the retailer’s profit function with respect to \(\psi \)

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _\mathrm{R}(\psi )=\frac{KL(\psi -1)^2(-bc+a)^2}{2(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2 \psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2\psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, the first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}\pi _\mathrm{R}}{\mathrm{d}\psi }=\frac{KL^2(\psi -1)(-bc+a)^2\alpha ^2(3\psi -1)}{2(4KLb \psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)^2} \end{aligned}$$

and the second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}^2\pi _\mathrm{R}}{\mathrm{d}\psi ^2}=\frac{-KL^2(-bc+a)^2\alpha ^2A_9}{(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)^3}. \end{aligned}$$

The second-order condition is negative if \(A_9>0.\) Thus, \(\pi _\mathrm{R}(\psi )\) is concave in \(\psi \) for the above condition. Solving the first-order condition for \(\psi \) gives \(\psi =\frac{1}{3}\) or \(\psi =1\).

When \(\psi =1\), \(A_9>0\) can be reduced to \(-L\alpha ^2>0\), which is a contradiction since \(L,K, \alpha ,\beta >0\).

Logically, the equilibrium \(\psi ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}=\frac{1}{3}\). Substituting the value of \(\psi ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}=\frac{1}{3}\) into the expressions accordingly, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \zeta ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}&= \frac{4K\beta (-bc+a)}{16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2}, \\ m^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}= & {} \frac{(-bc+a)(8Kb-3\alpha ^2)L}{b(16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2)}, \\ p^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}&= w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}+m^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}\\& = \frac{4KLb^2c-4Kb\beta ^2c-6L\alpha ^2bc+12KLab-3La\alpha ^2}{b(16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2)}, \\ w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}= & {} \frac{12KLbc-4K\beta ^2c-9L\alpha ^2c+4KLa}{16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2}, \\ \theta ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}&= \frac{6(-bc+a)L\alpha }{16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2}, \\ \pi _\mathrm{R}^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}& = \frac{2KL(-bc+a)^2}{16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2}, \\ \pi _\mathrm{F}^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}= & {} \frac{4(-bc+a)^2(4Kb-3\alpha ^2)L^2K}{(16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2)^2}, \\ \pi _\mathrm{SC}^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}= & {} \frac{2(-bc+a)^2(24KLb-4\beta ^2K-15L\alpha ^2)LK}{(16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition4

Proof

We can easily get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 2

Proof

During the computation process, the

$$\begin{aligned} \theta (\psi )=-\frac{(-bc\psi +a\psi +bc-a)L\alpha }{4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2 \psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2\psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

By computing the first-order derivative, we can obtain the result. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5

Proof

We prove the result about \(\zeta \); the result about w can be proved analogously. During the computation process, the

$$\begin{aligned} \zeta (\psi )=\frac{K\beta (-bc\psi ^2+a\psi ^2+2bc\psi -2a\psi -bc+a)}{4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2\psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

By computing the first-order derivative with respect to \(\psi \) and making analysis, we can obtain the result. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6

Proof

By computing the first-order derivative with respect to \(\psi \) and making analysis, we can obtain the result. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 7

Proof

The result can be proved analogously with Proposition 5. \(\square \)

Bargaining cost sharing contract model. Since the farmer and the retailer decide the \(\psi \) via bargaining, we formulate the objective function as

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\psi }\pi _\mathrm{F}\pi _\mathrm{R} \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Due to the game structure, we solve the farmer’s optimization problem first:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{w,\theta }\pi _\mathrm{F}=(w-c)q-\frac{1}{2}K(1-\psi )\theta ^2 \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w}=a-b(w+m)+\alpha \theta +\beta \zeta -(w-c)b,\\&\frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial \theta }=(w-c)\alpha -K\theta (1-\psi ), \end{aligned}$$

and the second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial w^2}=-2b, \\&\frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{F}}{ \partial \theta ^2}=-K(1-\psi ) , \\&\frac{ \partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial p\partial \zeta }=\alpha . \end{aligned}$$

We can write the Hessian matrix as

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{cc} -2b &{}\alpha \\ \alpha &{} -K(1-\psi ) \\ \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(28)

The Hessian matrix is negative definite if

$$\begin{aligned} 2bK(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2 > 0. \end{aligned}$$

Under this assumption, the farmer’s profit function is joint concave in p and \(\zeta \). Let the first-order condition be zero and solve equations for p and \(\zeta \). We can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} w(m,\zeta )=\frac{K(1-\psi )(bm-bc-\beta \zeta -a)+\alpha ^2c}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2} \end{aligned}$$
(29)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \theta (\zeta ,m)=-{\frac{\alpha \, \left( \beta \zeta -bc-bm+a \right) }{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}. \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Substituting Eqs. (2930) into the retailer’s profit function, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{m,\zeta }\pi _\mathrm{R}\,=\,& {} m\left( a-b \left( {\frac{ ( ( c-m ) b+\beta \zeta +a)( \psi -1) K+{\alpha }^{2} c}{2\,Kb\psi -2Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}+m \right) \right. \\&\left. -{\frac{{\alpha }^{2} ( \beta \zeta -bc-bm+a) }{2\,Kb\psi -2\,K b+{\alpha }^{2}}}+\beta \zeta \right) \\&-\frac{1}{2}L{\zeta }^ {2}-\frac{1}{2}{\frac{K{\alpha }^{2} ( \beta \zeta -bc -bm+a ) ^{2}\psi }{ ( 2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}) ^ {2}}}. \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m}\,=\, & {} a-b \left( {\frac{ \left( \left( c-m \right) b+\beta \, \left( \zeta \right) +a \right) \left( \psi -1 \right) K+{\alpha }^{2}c}{2\,Kb\psi - 2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}+m \right) \\&- {\frac{{\alpha }^{2} \left( \beta \, \left( \zeta \right) -bc-bm+a \right) }{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}} }+\beta \zeta \\&+m \left( -b \left( -{\frac{b \left( \psi -1 \right) K}{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}}+1 \right) \right. \\&+\left. {\frac{{ \alpha }^{2}b}{2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2}}} \right) \\&+{\frac{K{\alpha }^{2} \left( \beta \, \left( \zeta \right) -bc-bm+a \right) \psi \,b}{ \left( 2\,Kb\psi -2\,Kb+{\alpha }^{2} \right) ^{2}}},\\ \frac{\partial \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial \zeta }= & {} m\left( -\frac{b\beta (\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\right. \\&\left. - \frac{\alpha ^2\beta }{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+\beta \right) -L\zeta \\&-\frac{K\alpha ^2(\beta \zeta -bc-bm+a)\psi \beta }{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}, \end{aligned}$$

and the second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m^2}\,=\, & {} -2b\left( -\frac{b(\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+1\right) \\&+\frac{2\alpha ^2b}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\\&-\frac{K\alpha ^2b^2\psi }{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2},\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial \zeta ^2}= & {} -L-{\frac{K{\alpha }^{2}\beta ^2\psi }{ \left( 2\,Kb\psi +{\alpha }^{2}-2\,Kb \right) ^{2}}},\\ \frac{\partial ^2 \pi _\mathrm{R}}{ \partial m\partial \zeta }= & {} -\frac{b\beta (\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\\&- \frac{\alpha ^2\beta }{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+\beta +\frac{K\alpha ^2\beta \psi b}{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, the Hessian matrix is negative definite if

$$\begin{aligned}&-2b\left( -\frac{b(\psi -1)K}{2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}+1\right) +\frac{2\alpha ^2b}{2Kb \psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2}\\&\quad -\frac{K\alpha ^2b^2\psi }{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}<0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{b^2K(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2)}{(2Kb\psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}>0. \end{aligned}$$

Equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} -\frac{b^2K(4Kb\psi ^2-8Kb\psi +3\alpha ^2\psi +4Kb-2\alpha ^2)}{(2Kb \psi -2Kb+\alpha ^2)^2}<0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned}&4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi \\&\quad +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2>0 \end{aligned}$$

which implies

$$\begin{aligned} 4Kb\psi ^2-8Kb\psi +3\alpha ^2\psi +4Kb-2\alpha ^2>0 \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} L(4Kb\psi ^2-8Kb\psi +3\alpha ^2\psi +4Kb-2\alpha ^2)-K\beta ^2(\psi -1)^2>0. \end{aligned}$$

Let the first-order condition be zero and solve equations for m and \(\zeta \). We can get

$$\begin{aligned}&m=\frac{A_4}{b(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)}, \\&\zeta =\frac{K\beta (-bc\psi ^2+a\psi ^2+2bc\psi -2a\psi -bc+a)}{4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting m and \(\zeta \) into Eqs. (2930) and the Nash bargaining function (27). By computing the first-order condition and the second-order condition of the bargaining model

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\psi }\pi _\mathrm{F}\pi _\mathrm{R}. \end{aligned}$$

The first-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}\pi _\mathrm{B}}{\mathrm{d}\psi }=\frac{K^2L^2(\psi -1)^4(-cb+a)^4\alpha ^2A_1}{4(4KLb\psi ^2-K\beta ^2\psi ^2-8KLb\psi +2K\beta ^2\psi +3L\alpha ^2 \psi +4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)^4}. \end{aligned}$$

The second-order condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}^{2} \pi _\mathrm{B}}{\mathrm d\psi ^2}=-A_2\cdot \frac{K^2\alpha ^2L^3(-bc+a)^4}{2(4KLb\psi -2K\beta ^2\psi -4KLb+2K\beta ^2+L\alpha ^2)^5}. \end{aligned}$$

The second-order condition is negative if \(A_2<0.\) Thus, the objective function is concave in \(\psi \) for the above condition. Let the first-order condition be 0. We obtain \(\psi =1\),

$$\begin{aligned} \psi =\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2+A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}, \end{aligned}$$

or

$$\begin{aligned} \psi =\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2-A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

When \(\psi =1\), \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2>0\) can be deduced to \(-\alpha ^2>0\), which is a contradiction. Meanwhile, if

$$\begin{aligned} \psi =\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2+A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}, \end{aligned}$$

then the \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2>0\) is not satisfied. When

$$\begin{aligned} \psi\,=\,& {} \frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2+A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)},\\ 2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2\,=\, & {} \frac{12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2-2bA_3}{14Lb+\beta ^2}. \end{aligned}$$

If \(12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2<0\), then we can get \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2<0\); if \(12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2>0\), we only need to check \((12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2)^2-(2bA_3)^2\) is greater than or less than 0. By algebra,

$$\begin{aligned}&(12KLb^2-8L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2)^2-(2bA_3)^2\\&\quad =-\alpha ^2(14Lb+ \beta ^2)(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2). \end{aligned}$$

The problem transfers to verify whether \(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2\) is greater or less than 0. Since we have \(2KLb-\beta ^2K-L\alpha ^2>0\) and \(2Kb-\alpha ^2>0\), \(2b(2KLb-\beta ^2K-L\alpha ^2)>0\) and \(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-2\beta ^2Kb>0\). Owing to \(2Kb-\alpha ^2>0\), we can derive \(4KLb^2-2L\alpha ^2b-\alpha ^2\beta ^2>0\). Thus, \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2<0\) when

$$\begin{aligned} \psi =\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2+A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

Obviously, the

$$\begin{aligned} \psi =\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2+A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)} \end{aligned}$$

should be omitted. Analogously, we can also prove that \(2Kb(1-\psi )-\alpha ^2>0\) can be satisfied when

$$\begin{aligned} \psi =\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2-A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the equilibrium

$$\begin{aligned} \psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}=\frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2-A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

The equilibrium decisions and profit functions are

$$\begin{aligned}&\zeta ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{K\beta (-bc+a)(\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-1)^2}{4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2}, \\&m^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{A_4}{4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2}, \\&\theta ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{(-bc+a)(1-\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}})}{4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2}, \\&w^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{(3KLbc-K\beta ^2c+KLa)(\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-1)^2+3L\alpha ^2c(\psi _B^{*}-1)+L\alpha ^2c}{4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2}, \\&\pi _\mathrm{R}^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{KL(-bc+a)^2(\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-1)^2}{2(4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)}, \\&\pi _\mathrm{F}^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{(\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-1)^3(-bc+a)^2(2Kb\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-2Kb+\alpha ^2)KL^2}{2(4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)^2}, \\&\pi _\mathrm{SC}^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}\,=\,\frac{(\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-1)^2(-bc+a)^2 A_5 KL}{2(4KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}^2-8KLb{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+2K\beta ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+ 3L\alpha ^2{\psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}}+4KLb-K\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition 8

Proof

We can get the results from the computational process. \(\square \)

Model comparison.

Proof of Proposition 9

Proof

$$\begin{aligned} \psi ^{\mathrm{B}^{*}}-\frac{1}{3}\,=\, & {} \frac{8KLb+K\beta ^2-3L\alpha ^2-A_3}{K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}-\frac{1}{3}\\= & {} \frac{10KLb+2K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2-3A_3}{3K(14Lb+\beta ^2)}. \end{aligned}$$

We need to prove \(10KLb+2K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2-3A_3<0\) which is equivalent to \((10KLb+2K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2)^2-(3A_3)^2<0\). By algebra, we need to prove

$$\begin{aligned} -K(14Lb+\beta ^2)(16KLb-4K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2)<0, \end{aligned}$$

which is true since \(K>0\) and \(16KLb-4K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2>0\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 10

Proof

We prove \(w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}\) for example. The proofs of \(\theta ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>\theta ^{\mathrm{D}^{*}},\,p^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>p^{\mathrm{D}^{*}},\zeta ^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}>\zeta ^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}\) can be done analogously.

The \(w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}=\frac{12KLbc-4K\beta ^2c-9L\alpha ^2c+4KLa}{16KLb-4\beta ^2K-9L\alpha ^2}\) and the \(w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}=\frac{[L(3bc+a)-c\beta ^2]K-2Lc\alpha ^2}{4LbK-\beta ^2K-2L\alpha ^2}\). It is equivalent to prove \(\frac{w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}}{w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}}>1\).

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{w^{\mathrm{CS}^{*}}}{w^{\mathrm{D}^{*}}}>1&\Longleftrightarrow \frac{(12KLbc-4K\beta ^2c-9L\alpha ^2+4KLa)(4KLb-\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)}{(16KLb-4K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2)(3KLbc-K\beta ^2c-2L\alpha ^2c+KLa)}>1\\&\Longleftrightarrow (12KLbc-4K\beta ^2c-9L\alpha ^2+4KLa)(4KLb-\beta ^2-2L\alpha ^2)\\&\qquad -(16KLb-4K\beta ^2-9L\alpha ^2)(3KLbc-K\beta ^2c-2L\alpha ^2c+KLa)>0\\&\Longleftrightarrow KL^2\alpha ^2(-bc+a)>0. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Obviously, \(a-bc>0\) holds true. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 11

Proof

The proof can be obtained with the first-order derivative. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 12

Proof

The proof of (1) can be derived from Propositions 7 and 9; the proof of (2) is analogous to Proposition 10. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wang, G., Ding, P., Chen, H. et al. Green fresh product cost sharing contracts considering freshness-keeping effort. Soft Comput 24, 2671–2691 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-019-03828-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-019-03828-4

Keywords

Navigation