[go: up one dir, main page]
More Web Proxy on the site http://driver.im/
Skip to main content

Learning

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Simulating Social Complexity

Part of the book series: Understanding Complex Systems ((UCS))

  • 2393 Accesses

Abstract

Learning and evolution are adaptive or “backward-looking” models of social and biological systems. Learning changes the probability distribution of traits within an individual through direct and vicarious reinforcement, while evolution changes the probability distribution of traits within a population through reproduction and selection. Compared to forward-looking models of rational calculation that identify equilibrium outcomes, adaptive models pose fewer cognitive requirements and reveal both equilibrium and out-of-equilibrium dynamics. However, they are also less general than analytical models and require relatively stable environments. In this chapter, we review the conceptual and practical foundations of several approaches to models of learning that offer powerful tools for modeling social processes. These include the Bush-Mosteller stochastic learning model, the Roth-Erev matching model, feed-forward and attractor neural networks, and belief learning. Evolutionary approaches include replicator dynamics and genetic algorithms. A unifying theme is showing how complex patterns can arise from relatively simple adaptive rules.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    Much of the material in this chapter has been previously published in Macy (1996, 1997, 1998, 2004) Macy and Flache (2002), and Flache and Macy (2002).

  2. 2.

    A multilayer neural net requires a nonlinear activation function (such as a sigmoid). If the functions are linear, the multilayer net reduces to a single-layer I-O network.

  3. 3.

    However, if an input node is wired to hidden nodes as well as output nodes, the error for this node cannot be updated until the errors for all hidden nodes that it influenced have been updated.

  4. 4.

    The Cournot rule may be considered as a third degenerate model of belief learning. According to the Cournot rule, players assume that the behavior of the opponent in the previous round will always occur again in the present round.

References

  • Allison, P. (1992). The cultural evolution of beneficent norms. Social Forces, 71, 279–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandura, A. (1977). Social learning theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Börgers, T., & Sarin, R. (1997). Learning through reinforcement and replicator dynamics. Journal of Economic Theory, 77, 1–14.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bush, R. R., & Mosteller, F. (1950). Stochastic models for learning. New York: Wiley.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, D. E. (1971). The attraction paradigm. New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, D. E., & Griffitt, D. (1966). A development investigation of the law of attraction. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 4, 699–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cartwright, D., & Harary, F. (1956). Structural balance: A generalization of Heider’s theory. Psychological Review, 63, 277–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Catania, A. C. (1992). Learning (3rd ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Churchland, P. S., & Sejnowski, T. J. (1994). The computational brain. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M. D., Riolo, R., & Axelrod, R. (2001). The role of social structure in the maintenance of cooperative regimes. Rationality and Society, 13(1), 5–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, J. A. (1967). Clustering and structural balance in graphs. Human Relations, 20, 181–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durham, W. H. (1992). Coevolution: genes, culture and human diversity. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erev, I., & Rapoport, A. (1998). Coordination, “magic”, and reinforcement learning in a market entry game. Games and Economic Behavior, 23, 146–175.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Erev, I., & Roth, A. E. (1998). Predicting how people play games: Reinforcement learning in experimental games with unique, mixed strategy equilibria. American Economic Review, 88(4), 848–879.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erev, I., Bereby-Meyer, Y., & Roth, A. E. (1999). The effect of adding a constant to all payoffs: Experimental investigation, and implications for reinforcement learning models. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organizations, 39(1), 111–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flache, A., & Macy, M. W. (2002). Stochastic collusion and the power law of learning: A general reinforcement learning model of cooperation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(5), 629–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (1988). Passions within reason: The strategic role of the emotions. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Levine, D. (1998). The theory of learning in games. Boston: MIT Press.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, D. (1989). Genetic algorithms in search, optimization, and machine learning. New York: Addison-Wesley.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, W. (1964). The genetic evolution of social behaviour. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 17, 1–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. (1973). Games with randomly disturbed payoffs. International Journal of Game Theory, 2, 1–23.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Heider, F. (1958). The psychology of interpersonal relations. New York: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Herrnstein, R. J., & Drazin, P. (1991). Meliorization: A theory of distributed choice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(3), 137–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holland, J. (1975). Adaptation in natural and artificial systems. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holland, J. H., Holyoak, K. J., Nisbett, R. E., & Thagard, P. R. (1986). Induction: Processes of inference, learning, and discovery. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homans, G. C. (1951). The human group. New York: Harcourt Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hopfield, J. J. (1982). Neural networks and physical systems with emergent collective computational abilities. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 79, 2554–2558.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hopfield, J. J., & Tank, D. W. (1985). “Neural” computation of decisions in optimization problems. Biological Cybernetics, 52, 141–152.

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • James, W. (1981). Principles of psychology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopreato, J. (1990). From social evolutionism to biocultural evolutionism. Sociological Forum, 5, 187–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M. (1989). Walking out of social traps: A stochastic learning model for the prisoner’s dilemma. Rationality and Society, 2, 197–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M. (1991). Learning to cooperate: Stochastic and tacit collusion in social exchange. American Journal of Sociology, 97, 808–843.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M. (1996). Natural selection and social learning in prisoner’s dilemma: Co-adaptation with genetic algorithms and artificial neural networks. Sociological Methods and Research, 25, 103–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M. (1997). Identity, interest, and emergent rationality. Rationality and Society, 9, 427–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M. (1998). Social order in an artificial world. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 1(1). http://jasss.soc.surrey.ac.uk/1/1/4.html

  • Macy, M. (2004). Learning theory. In G. Ritzer (Ed.), Encyclopedia of social theory. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M., & Flache, A. (2002). Learning dynamics in social dilemmas. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 99, 7229–7236.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M., & Skvoretz, J. (1998). The evolution of trust and cooperation between strangers: A computational model. American Sociological Review, 63, 638–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macy, M., Kitts, J., Flache, A., & Benard, S. (2003). Polarization in dynamic networks: A Hopfield model of emergent structure. In R. Breiger & K. Carley (Eds.), Dynamic social network modeling and analysis: Workshop summary and papers (pp. 162–173). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G., & Simon, H. A. (1958). Organizations. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • McPherson, J. M., & Smith-Lovin, L. (1987). Homophily in voluntary organizations: status distance and the composition of face to face groups. American Sociological Review, 52, 370–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, A., & Vallacher, R. R. (1998). Toward computational social psychology: Cellular automata and neural network models of interpersonal dynamics. In S. J. Read & L. C. Miller (Eds.), Connectionist models of social reasoning and social behavior (pp. 277–311). Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Offerman, T. (1997). Beliefs and decision rules in public good games. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Quinlan, P. T. (1991). Connectionism and psychology: A psychological perspective on new connectionist research. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., & Erev, I. (1995). Learning in extensive-form games: Experimental data and simple dynamic models in intermediate term. Games and Economic Behavior, 8, 164–212.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Rumelhart, D. E., & McClelland, J. L. (1988). Parallel distributed processing: Explorations in the microstructure of cognition. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, S. H., & Ames, R. E. (1977). Positive and negative referent others as sources of influence: A case of helping. Sociometry, 40, 12–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun, R. (Ed.). (2008). The Cambridge handbook of computational psychology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, P. D., & Jonker, L. (1978). Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics. Mathematical Biosciences, 40, 145–156.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Thorndike, E. L. (1898). Animal intelligence: An experimental study of the associative processes in animals, Psychological Review, Monograph Supplements, No. 8. New York: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vanberg, V. (1994). Rules and choice in economics. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Williams, G. C. (1966). Adaptation and natural selection. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (1988). On human nature. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wynne-Edwards, V. C. (1962). Animal dispersion in relation to social behaviour. Edinburgh: Oliver & Boyd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wynne-Edwards, V. C. (1986). Evolution through group selection. Oxford: Blackwell Scientific.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, H. P. (1998). Individual strategy and social structure. An evolutionary theory of institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeggelink, E. (1994). Dynamics of structure: An individual oriented approach. Social Networks, 16, 295–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael W. Macy .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Further Reading

Further Reading

We refer readers interested in particular learning models and their application in agent-based simulation to Macy and Flache (2002), which gives a brief introduction into principles of reinforcement learning and discusses by means of simulation models how reinforcement learning affects behavior in social dilemma situations, whereas Macy (1996) compares two different approaches of modeling learning behavior by means of computer simulations. Fudenberg and Levine (1998) give a very good overview on how various learning rules relate to game-theoretic rationality and equilibrium concepts.

For some wider background reading, we recommend Macy (2004), which introduces the basic principles of learning theory applied to social behavior; Holland et al. (1986), which presents a framework in terms of rule-based mental models for understanding inductive reasoning and learning; and Sun (2008), which is a handbook of computational cognitive modeling.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Macy, M.W., Benard, S., Flache, A. (2017). Learning. In: Edmonds, B., Meyer, R. (eds) Simulating Social Complexity. Understanding Complex Systems. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-66948-9_20

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-66948-9_20

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-66947-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-66948-9

  • eBook Packages: Computer ScienceComputer Science (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics