1. Introduction
In the past one and half a decades, systemic risk measures have been extensively studied from different viewpoints and by different approaches. A systemic risk measure aims to quantify the systemic risk of a whole financial system. For a thorough overview of different approaches to systemic risk measures, we refer to Kromer et al. [
1]. The axiomatic approach to systemic risk measures was introduced by Chen et al. [
2]. They established an axiomatic framework for positive homogeneous systemic risk measures that contains the contagion model by Eisenberg and Noe [
3]. Further, Kromer et al. [
1] extended the axiomatic framework of Chen et al. [
2] to the convex systemic risk measures and to general measurable spaces. These axiomatic approaches to systemic risk measures share more or less the ideas of Artzner et al. [
4]. For other axiomatic approaches for systemic risk measures, we refer to [
5,
6,
7,
8,
9,
10,
11,
12,
13,
14]. For the dual representation results, we refer to [
15,
16,
17,
18,
19]. For the computation, we refer to [
18,
20,
21]. In this paper, we will be interested in and focus on the axiomatic approaches to systemic risk measures.
Axiomatic approaches to risk measures for single firms were initiated by Artzner et al. [
4], by introducing axiomatically the coherent risk measures and providing their representation. Further, the class of coherent risk measures was axiomatically extended to a broader class of convex risk measures by Föllmer and Schied [
22] and Frittelli and Rosazza Gianin [
23]. These risk measures are now also known as univariate risk measures, because the risk of a firm is described by a random gain/loss variable. For a comprehensive overview of univariate risk measures, we refer to Föllmer and Schied [
24]. Comonotonic additivity is an important notion in risk measure theory, especially in an axiomatic approach to risk measures. For instance, a so-called distortion risk measure satisfies this property of comonotonic additivity. Intuitively, comonotonic additivity says that the risk of the sum of two comonotonic random variables is just the sum of the risks of the two random variables. Financially, comonotonic additivity reflects that one can not reduce the total risk of a portfolio by spreading it among comonotonic components.
In this paper, we will incorporate the property of comonotonic additivity into the systemic risk measures, and hence establish a new class of systemic risk measures, which we refer to as strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measures (SRMs). Namely, first, we introduce the notions of the strong comonotonicity for two random vectors and the strong comonotonic additivity for systemic risk measures. Then, we provide structural decomposition for any strong comonotonic additive SRM. Moreover, when both the single-firm risk measure and the aggregation function in the structural decomposition are convex, the dual representation for it is also given. Finally, examples are given to illustrate the proposed strong comonotonic additive SRMs. At the same time, comparisons with existing SRMs are also made.
The main contribution of this paper is two-fold. One is the idea of the incorporation of comonotonic additivity for univariable risk measures into the systemic risk measures, which are multivariate risk measures. Such an idea of incorporation results in the introduction of the new notion of strong comonotonic additivity for SRMs, and therefore establish a new class of SRMs, which is rich; for examples, see
Section 5. The other is that the resulting aggregation function in the structural decomposition is only needed to be increasing (i.e., non-decreasing). This characteristic introduces more flexibility for the choice of suitable aggregation function and allows for SRMs without positive homogeneity or convexity, which are needed in Chen et al. [
2] and Kromer et al. [
1], respectively.
The rest of this paper is organised as follows. In
Section 2, we prepare preliminaries including the introduction of various definitions and notations.
Section 3 is devoted to the structural decomposition for strong comonotoninc additive SRMs. In
Section 4, if both the aggregation function and the single-firm risk measure in the structural decomposition are convex, then dual representation for strong comonotonic additive SRMs is provided. Finally, in
Section 5, examples, as well as comparisons with existing SRMs, are given to illustrate the proposed strong comonotonic additive SRMs.
2. Model and Notations
Consider a financial system consisting of n financial institutions/firms. The risk of a single firm means the random loss of the firm, which is described by a random variable. We use an n-dimensional random loss vector to represent the systemic risk of the financial system, in which each component of the n-dimensional random loss vector represents each firm’s random loss. Mathematically, let be a fixed measurable space. We denote by the set of all bounded random variables on , and by the set of all n-dimensional bounded random vectors. Denote by and the subsets of and whose elements are non-negative, respectively. An element of represents an economy of the financial system, and thus the systemic risks of different economies of the financial system can be described by the elements of . Operations on are understood component-wise. For instance, for , stands for means where means the real numbers. Denote all positive integers by means the dimensional Euclidean space. For a mapping with domain D and range R, for , denote Given a non-empty set A, stands for the indicator function of A, that is, if , and 0, otherwise. Throughout this paper, an increasing function means a non-decreasing function.
Now, we recall the definition of comonotonicity, and intruduce the notion of strong comonotonicity for two random vectors, which will play an important role in our study.
Definition 1 (comonotonicity). For , we call X and Y are comonotonic, if for any , Definition 2 (strong comonotonicity). For , we call and are strong comonotonic, if any pair of random variables from are comonotonic.
Next, we provide a useful equivalent description of strong comonotonicity of two random vectors, which has a same feature as that of two comonotonic random variables. Before doing so, we first state two relevant lemmas.
Lemma 1. Let be strong comonotonic. If there are such thatthenfor . Proof. For
such that
Then for any
, we multiply the above equality with
and obtain
Then all terms above are non-negative and add up to zero. Hence, all of them are null, and in particular
for any
. By repeating a similar procedure for
for
, we conclude that
for any
. This proves the lemma. □
By the same argument as in the proof of Lemma 1, we can steadily show the following Lemma 2, but we omit the detailed proof.
Lemma 2. Let be strong comonotonic. If there are such thatthenfor . Now, we are ready to state an equivalent description of the strong comonotonicity.
Proposition 1. - (1)
For , X and Y are comonotonic if and only if there exist a random variable and increasing functions such that and .
- (2)
For , and are strong comonotonic if and only if there exist a random variable and increasing functions such that , .
Proof. (1) It is a direct corollary of Denneberg ([
25], Proposition 4.5).
(2) By the same argument as in the proof of Denneberg ([
25], Proposition 4.5), we can steadily show the assertion. For the purpose of self-contained, we briefly provide a proof here. We only need to show the first part of the assertion, because the second part is a direct corollary of the previous item (1). Now, we proceed to show the existence of the desired random variable
and increasing functions
.
Let
. First, we define
,
on
,
. Note that for any
there is some
such that
We claim that any
has a unique decomposition
with
and some
, and then define
for
. We only need to show the uniqueness of the decomposition. Indeed, suppose that there are
such that
By Lemma 1, we know that for any
which just implies that the decomposition is unique.
Next, we turn to show that
,
are increasing on
,
Take
with
. Then there exist
such that
From Lemma 2, it follows that for any
,
which, as well as the definitions of
,
, yields that
for
. We have just shown that
,
are increasing on
,
and thus
,
.
It remains to be shown that
,
can be extended from
to
In fact, this can be steadily done by the similar arguments as in the proof of Denneberg ([
25], Proposition 4.5). Proposition 1 is proved. □
In general, a single-firm risk measure is any functional . Next, we state some basic properties (or axioms) for a single-firm risk measure .
- (R1)
Monotonicity: for any with .
- (R2)
Comonotonic additivity: for any such that X and Y are comonotonic.
- (R3)
Normalization: .
The Axioms (R1) and (R2) can be interpreted in the same way as in the definitions of coherent risk measures and distortion risk measures; for instance, see Artzner et al. [
4] and Wang et al. [
26]. Nevertheless, we briefly interpret them. Monotonicity means that the risk of a larger loss should not be less than the risk of a less loss. Comonotonic additivity means that spreading risk within comonotonic positions could not reduce the total risk. Note that given a single-firm risk measure
, for any
, the quantity
represents the capital requirement for
X, for instance, see Artzner et al. [
4]. Hence, normalization means that a deterministic loss should have a same amount capital requirement.
Now, we introduce the definition of normalized comonotonic additive single-firm risk measures.
Definition 3. A normalized comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure is a functional that satisfies the properties (R1)–(R3).
Notice that a single-firm risk measure
is said to be positive homogeneous, if
for any
and
It is said to be convex, if for any
and any
Next, we introduce the definition of an increasing aggregation function.
Definition 4. An increasing aggregation function is a function that satisfies the following properties:
- (A1)
Monotonicity: for any with .
- (A2)
-Surjectivity: .
Notice that a function
is said to be convex, if for any
and any
In general, a systemic risk measures is any functional . Next, we introduce some properties (or axioms) for a systemic risk measure.
- (S1)
Monotonicity: for any with .
- (S2)
Preference consistency: For any if for all , then .
- (S3)
-Surjectivity: .
- (S4)
Strong comonotonic additivity: For any such that and are strong comonotonic, if for all , then .
The Axioms (S1), (S1) and (S3) can be interpreted in the same way as in the definition of convex systemic risk measures; for instance, see Chen et al. [
2] and Kromer et al. [
1]. For the formulation of the strong comonotonic additivity property, we start with the systemic risk of the deterministic
that is the sum of the systemic risk of deterministic
and
for all
, in which
and
are strong comonotonic. Then the strong comonotonic additivity property requires that the systemic risk of the random vector
is just the systemic risk of the sum of the systemic risks of the random vectors
. This means that the introduction of “randomness” should not change the systemic risk of
on the systemic risk of the sum of the systemic risks of
and
.
For a systemic risk measure , denote by the restriction of on when is considered as all degenerate random vectors. Hence, together with (S1)–(S3), we obtain a measurable function from to , and plugging in a function , , results in the composition . Note that
We end this section by introducing the definition of strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measures.
Definition 5. A strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure is a functional that satisfies the properties (S1)–(S4) and .
Notice that a systemic risk measure
is said to be positive homogeneous, if
for any
and
. It is said to be convex, if for any
and any
3. Structural Decomposition
In this section, we establish structural decomposition for any strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure, which states that any strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure can be decomposed into a comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure and an increasing aggregation function.
Now, we state the structural decomposition for strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measures, which is one of the main results of this paper.
Theorem 1. A functional is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure if and only if there exist an increasing aggregation function and a normalized comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure , such that ρ is the composition of and Λ, that is,for all . Proof. Sufficiency. Assume that a systemic risk measure
is of a form of (
2). We claim that
is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure. In fact,
For
,
with
, it holds
for all
. For
, denote by
the composition of
and
, that is,
From the monotonicity of
, it follows that for all
,
which means that
. Hence, by the monotonicity of
,
which means that
, and thus
is monotone.
- (S2)
Preference consistency:
Since
is monotonic and comonotonic additive, by Lemma 4.83 of Föllmer and Schied [
24],
is positive homogeneous. Moreover, note that
is normalized. Hence, for any
,
For any
,
such that
for all
, by (
2) we know that for any
,
which, together with (
5), implies that
for all
, and thus
. Therefore, from the monotonicity of
, it follows that
which means that
satisfies the preference consistency.
The
-Surjectivity of
is a direct corollary of the
-Surjectivity of
and (
5).
- (S4)
Strong comonotonic additivity:
For
,
,
, suppose that
and
are strong comonotonic and satisfy
for all
. By (
2), we know that
for all
. By (
5) and (
10), we have that
for all
, that is,
.
Since
and
are strong comonotonic, by Proposition 1(2), there exist a random variable
and increasing functions
such that
,
. Hence,
From (
12) and the monotonicity of
, it follows that
and
are increasing functions of
Z. Therefore by Proposition 1(1), we know that
and
are comonotonic. Consequently, by (
11) and the comonotonic additivity of
, we obtain that
which means that
satisfies strong comonotonic additivity.
:
Since
is
Surjective, by Lemma 2.3 (b) of Kromer et al. [
1],
which, together with (
5), yields
.
In summary, is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure.
Necessity: Assume that a systemic risk measure
is strong comonotonic additive. We claim that there exist an increasing aggregation function
and a comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure
, such that for all
,
In fact, define
for any
.
Since
is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure,
and thus it follows from the definition of
as in (
14) that
, where
and the composition
is defined by
for all
.
Note again that
. For any
there exists
such that
. Therefore, we can define a functional
by
for any
, where
satisfies
We claim that
is well-defined. In fact, given arbitrarily
consider
such that
. Then we have
for all
. Thus,
for all
. Hence, the preference consistency of
implies
, and therefore
is well-defined. Moreover, by the definitions of
and
, we know that
that is
for any
.
Now, all that remain is to show that is an increasing aggregation function and is a comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure. First, we show that is an increasing aggregation function.
For any
with
, by the monotonicity of
,
which, together with (
14), gives rise to
The
-Surjectivity of
is a direct corollary of the
-Surjectivity of
and (
14).
In a word, is an increasing aggregation function. Next, we turn to show that is a comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure.
For
with
, there exist
such that
,
.
implies that for any
,
Both (
14) and (
19) lead to
for all
, and thus
, since
is preference consistent. By the definition of
as in (
15), we have that
, which yields that
is monotone.
- (R2)
Comonotonic additivity:
For any
such that
X and
Y are comonotonic, we are about to prove
Define
Let
By the definitions of
f and
, it is not hard to verify that
By (
14) and (
22), for any
,
Since
is monotone and
-surjective,
f is increasing and surjective. Hence,
is an increasing function. Since
X and
Y are comonotonic, by Proposition 1 (1), there exist increasing functions
and random variable
such that
,
. Note that
and
are increasing functions. By Proposition 1,
are comonotonic and thus
are strong comonotonic. Therefore, from (
25) and the strong comonotonic additivity of
, it follows that
By (
14), (
24) and (
26), we have that
which is just (
21).
Since
is increasing and surjective, there exists
such that
. Since
is monotone and comonotone additive, by Exercise 11.1 of Denneberg [
25],
is positively homogeneous. Both (
16) and (
22) yield that
Meanwhile, by (
14) and (
22),
Therefore, (
28) and (
29) together imply that
which shows that
is normalized.
In summary, is a normalized comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure. Theorem 1 is proved. □
Notice that if the single-firm risk measure
and the aggregation function
in (
2) are convex, then the systemic risk measure
being of the form of (
2) is also convex.
Remark 1. Note that by Remark 2.4 of Kromer et al. [
1],
if one requires that the range of Λ is and that is bijective on , then it holds that .
As a result, it can be verified that in the proof of Theorem 1, if we replace (A2) by
- (A2*)
-Surjectivity: ,
- (S3)
by
- (S3*)
-Surjectivity: ,
and by , then Theorem 1 still holds for , and . In this case, we call a non-negative strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure, that is, it is a functional satisfying the properties (S1), (S2), (S3*), (S4) and . The corresponding is called a non-negative increasing aggregation function, that is, it is a function satisfying the properties (A1) and (A2*). is called a non-negative normalized comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure, that is, it is a functional satisfying the properties (R1)–(R3).
Remark 2. Note that by Remark 2.4 of Kromer et al. [1], if one requires that the range of Λ is for some and that is bijective from some interval to , then it holds that .
As a result, it can be verified that in the proof of Theorem 1, if we replace by
- (A2**)
Interval-Surjectivity: ,
- (S3)
by
- (S3**)
Interval-Surjectivity: ,
and by , then Theorem 1 holds for , and . In this case, we call an interval-bounded strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure, that is, it is a functional satisfying the properties (S1), (S2), (S3*), (S4) and .
4. Representation Results
In this section, we provide the dual representation for strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measures, if both the single-firm risk measure and the aggregation function in the structural decomposition are convex.
We begin with recalling the definition of Choquet integral with respect to monotone set functions.
Definition 6. A monotone set function on is a set function satisfying
- (1)
,
- (2)
, for any with .
A monotone set function μ is said to be normalized, if .
Definition 7. Given a monotone set function , then for any random variable , the Choquet integral of X with respect to μ is defined by Next, we provide representations for strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measures in terms of Choquet integral. Before doing so, inspirited by Kromer et al. [
1], we first define the acceptance set of an aggregation function
by
Now, we are ready to state a primal representation for strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measures in terms of Choquet integral, which is not only one of the main results of this paper, but also crucial for later dual representation, see Theorem 4 below.
Theorem 2. Assume that is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure with the decomposition . Then there exists a normalized monotone set function such that for any ,where means Remark 3. Note that in the Theorem 2, is defined byBy (34) below, we will know that , and hence ξ is a random variable. Proof of Theorem 2. Since
is normalized, monotone and comonotonic additive, by Schmeidler’s Representation Theorem (for example, see Schmeidler [
27] or Theorem 11.2 of Denneberg [
25]), there exists a normalized monotone set function
such that
for any
, where
for any
By (
33) we have that for any
,
. Note that obviously,
for any
. Therefore, by the definition of
for any
,
Consequently, for any
which implies that the first equality in (
32) holds.
To show the second equality in (
32), it suffices to show that the integral and infimum in (
32) can be interchanged. Indeed, given arbitrarily
for any
such that
we have
Hence, by the monotonicity of Choquet integral, we obtain that
and thus
On the other hand, taking into account the fact that
yields
which, along with (
35) and (
36), implies (
32). Theorem 2 is proved. □
Under some additional assumptions, the monotone set function
as in (
32) can be represented in the form of a distorted probability. Assume that
P is a fixed probability measure on
. Suppose that
is a distortion function, that is, it is an increasing function with
,
. Then the composition
is called a distorted probability, which is a monotone set function on
. We continue to introduce more notations. For
, we denote by
the distribution function of
X with respect to
P, that is,
,
. For
, we say that
Y dominates
X in the sense of first order stochastic dominance (FSD), denoted by
, if
for all
. We say that the probability space
is atomless, if for any
with
, there exists
such that
.
Theorem 3. Assume that is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure with the decomposition . Suppose that ρ further satisfies the following property
- (S2*)
FSD-preserving: For with and , if , then .
Then, there exists a function such that for any , In addition, if is atomless, then g is a distortion function and hence is a distorted probability.
Proof. We first show the existence of the function
g. Note that
has a representation as in (
32), it is sufficient for us to prove that for any
,
with some function
. In fact, checking the proof of Theorem 2, we know that for any
Recall that
. We first define a function
as follows: for any
with some
such that
We claim that the function
g is well-defined on
In fact, given
, let
such that
Then the distribution functions of
and
are the same. Hence,
and
. Since
, there exist
,
such that
and
. Hence, from (S2*), it follows that
, and thus
due to the decomposition of
. Therefore, by (
38), we have that
, which indicates that the function
g is well-defined on
Now, we can extend the function
g from
to
freely, because those
do not matter. Apparently, by the definition of
g, we know that
.
Next, assume that
is atomless. By Proposition A.31 of Föllmer and Schied [
24], there is a random variable
X on
with a continuous distribution function. Define
. Then,
U is uniformly distributed on
. For any
denote
Then,
and
Hence, taking (
38) into account, for any
we have that
Note that the normalization, monotonicity and comonotonic additivity of
imply the positive homogeneity of
, and hence
for example, see Lemma 4.83 of Föllmer and Schied [
24]. Thus,
,
For any
,
, which indicates that
g is increasing on
Clearly,
Therefore,
g is a distortion function and
is a distorted probability. Theorem 3 is proved. □
Taking Theorem 1 into account, if the comonotonic additive single-firm risk measure
and the increasing aggregation function
in the structural decomposition are convex, then the corresponding strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure
is convex, and thus
should have a dual representation. Before we investigate the dual representation for
, let us introduce some more notations. Notice that the space
of all bounded random variables on
is a Banach space if endowed with the supremum norm,
Denote by
the space of all continuous linear functionals on
We also endow
with a supremum norm
,
Then
is a Banach space. We denote by
the space of all continuous linear functionals on
. It is well known that
, the product space of
.
A mapping
is called a finitely additive set function if
, and if for any finite collection
of mutually disjoint sets
We denote by
the set of all those finitely additive set functions
, which are normalized to
The total variation of a finitely additive set function
is defined as
We denote by
the space of all finitely additive set functions
whose total variation is finite. For the convenience of statement, a finitely additive set function is also called a finitely additive measure.
For the integration theory with respect to a measure
, we refer to Föllmer and Schied [
24] (pp. 505–506). By Theorem A.51 of Föllmer and Schied [
24], we know that
is just
. Apparently,
contains
, and we will denote the integral of a random variable
with respect to
by
Now, we are in a position to state the dual representation for a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure, which is also one of the main results of this paper.
Theorem 4. Assume that is a strong comonotonic additive systemic risk measure with the decomposition . If both and Λ are convex, then for any ,whereandfor and , where is as in (31). Proof. By Theorem 2, there exists a normalized monotone set function
such that
Since both
and
are convex, by the structural decomposition of
, we know that
is also convex. Hence, from (
43) and Theorem 4.94 of Föllmer and Schied [
24], it follows that
where
.
By checking the proof of Theorem 2, we know that for any
,
Therefore, (
44) and (
45) together imply that
where
.
Taking (
43) and (
46) into account, it is sufficient for us to prove that for any
and
,
where
is as in (
42).
We will show (
47) by an argument similar to the proof of Theorem 4.3 of Kromer et al. [
1]. Define an indicator function of
,
as
Clearly,
The conjugate function of
is the function
defined by
for
Since
is closed and
is continuous due to its convexity, by the duality theorem for conjugate functions we have that for any
and
,
Given
and
, consider
defined by
By (
49) and (
51),
Since
is upper semi-continuous and concave, by Theorem 6 of Rockafellar [
28],
is the Lagrangian of the minimization problem “minimize
f over
” with
and
defined by
where
. It can be verified that
Let
be defined as
for
. Then
. Since
and
are convex and hence continuous, it follows that
is lower semi-continuous. By Theorem 7 of Rockafellar [
28], we can interchange the supremum and the infimum in (
52). Thus,
Meanwhile, it can be observed that
which, together with (
55), exactly implies that (
47) holds. Theorem 4 is proved. □