We applied the generalized difference-in-difference method to investigate the causal relationship between the implementation of the RCS policy and two variables of interest: COD emissions and polluting firms’ net operating profits. (Both the net operating profits and the net total profits could be obtained from the ASIFs). Since different pilot prefectures started the RCS in different years, we used the following specification as the basic regression model in this paper. (Pilot prefectures and the starting years were as follows: Shanghai (2012), Tianjin (2012), Jiangsu Province (Wuxi (2007), Changhzou, Suzhou, and Suqian (2008), Yancheng, Huaian, and Taizhou (2009), Yangzhou (2010), Zhenjiang, Nantong, and Lianyungang (2011), Xuzhou and Nanjing (2013)), Zhejiang Province (Haining (2011), Taizhou, Ningbo, Shaoxing, and Jiaxing (2012), Wenzhou, Hangzhou, Huzhou, and Jiangshan (2013)), Anhui Province (Huangshan (2012), Hefei (2013)), Shandong Province (Heze (2012)), Hubei Province (Shiyan and Huanggang (2009)), Henan Province (Zhoukou (2009), Luohe (2012)), Liaoning Province (Dalian and Shenyang (2008)), and Heilongjing Province (Qiqihaer (2010))).
where
is
and
, representing the log of the annual COD emissions and the log of the net operating profit of firm
i located in prefecture
k in year
t;
is a dummy variable that equals 1 if prefecture
k has implemented the river chief system by year
t. According to previous studies on water pollution,
is a set of control variables at the firm level, including (1) a dummy variable indicating whether a firm exports; (2) the log of the firm’s net asset value; (3) the log of the firm’s number of employees; (4) a dummy variable indicating whether the firm has loan; (5) the firm’s investment; (6) the age of the firm; (7) the squared age of the firm.
and
are fixed effects for the firm and year.
is the error term.
For the robustness of the estimation, we next verified whether the sample satisfied the parallel trend assumption [
14]. We constructed the following regression model, as in the classic approach [
15]:
where
is
and
,
is a dummy variable that equals 1 if it is the
year before or after the implementation of the RCS,
is a dummy variable that equals 1 if prefecture
k is one of the pilot prefectures in the sample period, and
and
are fixed effects for the firm and year. If estimates of
do not have a significant difference between the treatment group and the control group, the parallel trend assumption is satisfied.
Heterogeneity
This section explores the heterogeneous impacts of the RCS across firms of different industries, regions, ownership, and location. Heterogeneity may exist because of the difference in local governments’ regulations. For example, according to the extant literature, firms of different ownership are regulated differently [
16]. Prefectures in different regions also implement regulation policies of different levels of stringency. According to the extant literature, the eastern provinces in China generally implement more strict emission regulations than other provinces [
17]. At the industry level, heavily polluting industries are generally regulated more strictly [
8]. From the angle of free-riding, much of the literature has found that pollution regulation is loose at provincial boundaries [
9,
10].
We started by investigating how the river chief system affected the COD emissions and profits of polluting firms in different industries. According to the extant literature, we categorized the 36 two-digit polluting industries into industries of heavy, moderate, and light pollution, as shown in
Table 3 [
18].
We next applied the regression model (
1) to the three sub-samples of the heavily polluting, moderately polluting, and lightly polluting industries.
Table 4 presents the results.
Obviously, the RCS significantly reduced the COD emissions in heavily polluting industries by 6.3%, while it significantly increased their profits by 5.5%. Both effects were significant at 1%. The other two industries also reduced their COD emissions, but the effect was not statistically significant. Firms in moderately polluting industries, on average, experienced an increase in profit by 2.5% after the RCS at the significance level of 5%, while the profits of firms in lightly polluting industries were not affected by the RCS.
Table 3 confirms our conjecture about emission abatement—that local governments mainly targeted heavily polluting industries. It is also worth mentioning that, according to the Chow test, which is used to examine whether the true coefficients in two linear regressions on different datasets are equal, the percentage of profit increase in heavily polluting firms was larger than that in moderately polluting firms. The discrepancies in profits among industries indicate a possible transfer of the negative shock from RCS along the production line; on average, heavily polluting industries were located the furthest upstream on the production chain among the three industries, while lightly polluting industries were located the furthest downstream. As the extant literature suggests, environmental regulation can also affect the output price [
19]. If the upstream industries have more bargaining power in determining the prices of intermediate inputs, their profits could increase, even with significant reductions in COD emissions. In contrast, it is generally more difficult for firms in lightly polluting industries to transfer the burden to consumers in the consumption market because consumption price stability has always been one of the main targets of the Chinese government. We will discuss the influencing channels through which the RCS affects firms’ profits in more detail in
Section 4.
We next checked how the impacts of the RCS differed across regions by running the regression model (
1) on the four sub-samples of eastern, northeastern, central, and western China based on the central government’s classification.
Table 5 presents the results.
The first observation is that the RCS generated a heterogenous effect across the regions. It significantly reduced polluting firms’ COD emissions in eastern China and northeastern China by 3.2% and 10% at the level of 5%, but it also significantly increased firms’ profits in the eastern provinces by 2.9% at the level of 1%. The Chow test verified that the emission abatement in the eastern provinces was larger than that in the northeastern provinces. In contrast, the RCS significantly increased polluting firms’ COD emissions in central and western China by 33% and 47% at the level of 1%, and it also increased firms’ profits in the central provinces by 8%. However, the magnitudes of the coefficients of emission in these two regions were not statistically different. This pattern confirms our conjectures that the eastern provinces put stringent regulations on emission abatement. (Because of the high population density and the high level of average income in eastern China, citizens are more concerned about their health than those in other regions of China. Hence, local governments’ incentives for environmental protection are also strong.) Moreover, consistently with the extant literature, the central and western provinces fit the “pollution paradise” hypothesis: Polluting firms tend to invest in the central and western provinces, where local governments emphasize economic development more, as compared to the local governments in the eastern provinces [
5,
20]. Despite the increase in COD emissions, the profits of polluting firms in the western provinces were not affected.
We next checked the possible heterogeneity with respect to enterprise ownership. Compared to private firms and foreign firms, state-owned firms usually gave higher priority to social responsibility than profit maximization, and could thereby be assigned more stringent abatement targets; however, political protection from local governments and the attempt to stabilize employment suggest that state-owned firms may receive less stringent regulations. Hence, the effect of the RCS on state-owned firms is ambiguous. Foreign firms primarily have advanced abatement technologies and, hence, a lower cost of emission abatement [
21]. Private firms generally have no technological advantage compared to foreign firms, and they receive, on average, less political protection from local governments than state-owned firms do. Therefore, the negative impact of the RCS may be the largest for private firms. We ran the specification (
1) on the three sub-samples of state-owned, private, and foreign firms, and the results are presented in
Table 6.
As we anticipated, local governments’ conflict concerns for state-owned firms made the impact of the RCS on their emission abatement ambiguous; state-owned firms’ COD emissions were not significantly affected. Their profits increased by 11.7% at the significance level of 1%. Private firms and foreign firms reduced their COD emissions by 4.4% and 6.8%, respectively. Nonetheless, private firms’ profits were not affected, while foreign firms’ profits increased by 4.1% at the significance level of 1%. These results also confirmed foreign firms’ technological advantages. The Chow test verified that the emission abatement by foreign firms was larger than that by private firms and that the increase in the profits of state-owned firms was larger than that of foreign firms.
We next explored the free-riding incentive at provincial boundaries. Extant studies about water pollution reveal that, at provincial boundaries along a river, upstream firms face less stringent regulations than downstream firms [
9,
10]. Since some prefectures in Jiangsu province and Zhejiang province share the Tai Lake, we checked the emission behaviors at the provincial boundaries without identifying the “upstream” and “downstream” regions.
Table 7 presents the regression results of the specification (
1) on the two sub-samples: the sub-sample of firms located near provincial boundaries, defined as firms that were located in districts or counties at provincial boundaries, and the sub-sample of firms in the interior of a province [
10].
The RCS significantly reduced interior polluting firms’ COD emissions by 5.6% at the level of 1%, while it also increased their profits by 2.6% at the significance level of 1%. In contrast, the RCS did not affect the COD emissions of polluting firms at provincial boundaries, but it did increase their profits by 4.7%. The results regarding emission abatement at provincial boundaries verified the free-riding problem identified by previous studies. The Chow test also verified that the increase in profits of firms at provincial boundaries was larger than that of those in the interior.
To further explore the reason behind the above heterogenous results, we classified polluting firms in different regions by their levels of pollution. Because neither the COD emissions nor the profits of light-polluting firms were significantly affected by the RCS in any regions, we only present the results for heavily and moderately polluting firms in
Table 8 and
Table 9.
The first observation from
Table 8 is that provinces in different regions appeared to assign the abatement tasks to different industries after implementing the RCS. Eastern provinces focused on heavily polluting industries, while northeastern provinces and central provinces focused on moderately and lightly polluting industries, respectively. Heavily and moderately polluting industries in the RCS pilot prefectures of the central provinces increased their COD emissions significantly. In the RCS pilot prefectures of the western provinces, firms of moderately polluting industries increased their COD emissions, and the magnitude was statistically larger than that of firms in the central provinces according to the Chow test.
Table 9 indicates that in the eastern provinces, only heavily polluting industries’ profits were significantly affected by the RCS, despite the significant emission abatement; the profits increased by 5.1% at the significance level of 1%. Similarly, in the northwestern provinces, firms in moderately polluting industries managed to increase their profits by 5.1% despite the emission abatement. Although firms in heavily and moderately polluting industries in the central provinces increased their COD emissions, only firms in moderately polluting industries experienced an increase in profits. This increase, however, was not statistically different from the increase in profits of moderately polluting firms in the northeastern provinces.
We next classified polluting firms of different ownership types by their levels of pollution.
Table 10 and
Table 11 present the results.
Table 10 indicates that the COD emissions of state-owned firms were not affected by the RCS, regardless of the industry. In heavily polluting industries, emission abatement of private firms and foreign firms contributed the most to the results of the full sample in
Table 4. However, state-owned and foreign firms in heavily polluting industries in the pilot prefectures increased their profits, which is consistent with
Table 6. However, the magnitudes of the two coefficients were not statistically different.
We finally investigated how the RCS affected interior and boundary firms of different pollution levels. The results are presented in
Table 12 and
Table 13.
Interior firms in the heavily polluting industries of the pilot prefectures managed to reduce the COD emissions and increase the profits, which is consistent with
Table 4. Heavily polluting firms of the pilot prefectures on provincial boundaries experienced an increase in profits without reducing their COD emissions, which is consistent with
Table 7. Interior firms in moderately polluting industries managed to increase their profits by 2.7%. In lightly polluting industries, interior firms reduced their emissions while their profits were not significant affected. Boundary firms did not change their COD emission levels, but increased their profits by 8%. This was the only case in which firms in lightly polluting industries increased their profits.